Marion Diagnostic Center, LLC v. Becton Dickinson & Co., No. 21-1513 (7th Cir. 2022)

Annotate this Case
Justia Opinion Summary

A putative class of medical providers sued, alleging a conspiracy to drive up the prices of syringes and safety IV catheters (Products). Their first complaint, alleging a hub‐and‐spokes conspiracy ( Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1) between manufacturer, BD, group purchasing organizations, and four distributors, was dismissed because the Providers failed to allege that the distributors coordinated with each other in furtherance of the conspiracy. In an amended complaint, the Providers abandoned their horizontal conspiracy allegations and alleged two vertical conspiracies, one between BD and McKesson and another between BD and Cardinal Health.

The district court dismissed, noting that because the named plaintiffs do not purchase the Products directly from Cardinal, they lack “antitrust standing” to sue Cardinal. The Seventh Circuit affirmed. . The Providers cannot sue Cardinal under Article III because their injury is not fairly traceable to Cardinal’s conduct; precedent precludes the suit because they do not purchase the Products from either member of the BD‐Cardinal conspiracy. The Providers did not plausibly establish that vertical conspiracies involving just two distributors and BD could influence the prices that the Providers pay, regardless of which distributor they purchase from, and regardless of the fact that there are at least four major distributors.

Download PDF
In the United States Court of Appeals For the Seventh Circuit ____________________ No. 21 1513 MARION DIAGNOSTIC CENTER, LLC and MARION HEALTHCARE, LLC, Plaintiffs Appellants, v. BECTON DICKINSON & CO., CARDINAL HEALTH, INC., and MCKESSON MEDICAL SURGICAL, INC., Defendants Appellees. ____________________ Appeal from the United States District Court for the Southern District of Illinois. No. 3:18 cv 01059 — Nancy J. Rosenstengel, Chief Judge. ____________________ ARGUED NOVEMBER 12, 2021 — DECIDED MARCH 18, 2022 ____________________ Before SYKES, Chief Judge, and RIPPLE and ST. EVE, Circuit Judges. ST. EVE, Circuit Judge. A putative class of medical provid ers brought this suit alleging a conspiracy to drive up the prices of conventional syringes, safety syringes, and safety IV catheters (“the Products”). The Providers’ First Amended Complaint (“FAC”) alleged a hub and spokes conspiracy 2 No. 21 1513 between manufacturer Becton, Dickinson & Co. (“BD”), group purchasing organizations, and four distributors of the Products in violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. The district court dismissed the FAC for failure to state a claim. When we first considered this case on appeal, we agreed: the Providers’ failure to allege that the distributors coordinated with each other in furtherance of the conspiracy doomed their claims on the merits. Marion Healthcare, LLC v. Becton Dickin son & Co. (Marion I), 952 F.3d 832, 842–43 (7th Cir. 2020). None theless, we vacated and remanded so the Providers could amend their complaint one more time. In their Second Amended Complaint (“SAC”), the Provid ers abandoned their horizontal conspiracy allegations and now allege two vertical conspiracies: (1) between BD and McKesson Medical Surgical, Inc. (“McKesson”), and (2) be tween BD and Cardinal Health, Inc. (“Cardinal”).1 The district court once again dismissed the SAC for failure to state a claim. The court also concluded that because the named plainti s do not purchase the Products directly from Cardinal, they lack “antitrust standing” to sue Cardinal under Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 (1977). As explained below, we a rm. I. Background A. Allegations in the SAC Marion Diagnostic Center, LLC and Marion Healthcare, LLC are small healthcare providers in Marion, Illinois. Like many such providers, they join group purchasing organiza tions (“GPOs”), which negotiate contracts on behalf of their 1 According to Defendants, Plaintiffs erroneously named Cardinal Health, Inc. as a Defendant. The relevant distribution entity is Cardinal Health 200, LLC. No. 21 1513 3 members for medical products. These GPO manufacturer contracts are known as “Net Dealer Contracts.” GPOs present the terms of the Net Dealer Contracts to providers, who can either accept the terms or attempt to negotiate directly with a manufacturer. If a provider accepts the terms of a Net Dealer Contract, the provider then enters a “Distribution Agree ment” with a distributor.2 Under this scenario, a provider purchases medical products directly from a distributor, who charges the prices agreed to in the Net Dealer Contract plus a markup for the distributor’s services. BD is the leading national manufacturer of the three prod ucts at issue: BD controls 60% of the market for conventional syringes, 60% of the market for safety syringes, and 55% of the market for safety IV catheters. According to the Providers, these products are commodities, meaning that they are effec tively interchangeable with competitors’ products. Nonethe less, BD charges significantly higher prices than its competi tors: 11% more for conventional syringes, 36% more for safety syringes, and 37% more for safety IV catheters. 2 The Providers argue that the Distribution Agreements often have one sided termination clauses, meaning that distributors can terminate those contracts, but providers cannot. Defendants object that the Providers in appropriately supplemented the SAC through their brief opposing the motion to dismiss. Compare Agnew v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 683 F.3d 328, 348 (7th Cir. 2012) (“[I]t is a basic principle that the complaint may not be amended by the briefs in opposition to a motion to dismiss, nor can it be amended by the briefs on appeal.”), with United States ex rel. Hanna v. City of Chicago, 834 F.3d 775, 779 (7th Cir. 2016) (Rule 8 allows a plaintiff to add facts to the complaint “by affidavit or brief—even a brief on ap peal.”). Because this fact does not alter our analysis, we need not decide whether the Providers raised it too late. 4 No. 21 1513 Cardinal and McKesson are two of the largest distributors of the Products. The distribution market entails warehousing, processing orders, marketing, and tech support. Notably, the Providers have not alleged that either Cardinal or McKesson has market power in the distribution market, which includes at least four major players. The Providers also concede that they do not purchase BD products from Cardinal. They allege only that they have purchased the Products from McKesson. Complicating matters further, the Distributors make “Dealer Notification Agreements” with BD, in which the Distributors agree to distribute BD’s Products in accordance with the Net Dealer Contracts. Plaintiffs allege that BD is engaged in two vertical conspir acies to restrain trade in the relevant product markets. Specif ically, they allege that BD has a quid pro quo with Cardinal and McKesson. First, the Net Dealer Contracts lock providers into long term contracts for BD products through sole source or dual source provisions, “penalty pricing” rebate provi sions, and bundling. Second, Cardinal and McKesson enforce those contracts, monitor providers’ compliance, and supply BD with purchasing information, going above and beyond the terms of the Distributors’ contractual obligations to BD. Third, Cardinal and McKesson coerce providers into buying only BD products through alleged misrepresentations about the quality or availability of competitors’ products, even when doing so is inconsistent with their own self interest. Cardinal, for example, allegedly promotes BD’s products over its competing in house brand, Covidien. Fourth, BD rewards these Distributors with various incentives. The Providers allege that BD has engaged in other anti competitive acts in furtherance of the conspiracies. Namely, No. 21 1513 5 BD has made false claims about its own products while dis paraging the products of its rival, Retractable, and BD has been found liable for infringing Retractable’s patents. Addi tionally, BD has entered exclusionary contracts with large healthcare providers (outside the GPO system) that bundle the three products at issue with other BD products. These al legations appeared in the FAC, which this court previously held failed to state a claim. Marion I, 952 F.3d at 842–43. According to the Providers, all of this conduct amounts to antitrust injury by allowing BD to inflate the prices of the Products above competitive levels. The SAC further alleges that the conspiracies harm innovation in the relevant product markets by deterring potential entrants, thereby reducing product quality and safety. B. Dismissal of the FAC In the FAC, the Providers alleged a hub and spokes con spiracy between BD, Cardinal, McKesson, two other distribu tors, and two GPOs in violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1.3 The district court dismissed the FAC based on a misap plication of Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 (1977). In Illinois Brick, the Supreme Court held that a direct purchaser from an alleged monopolist or cartel member is the proper party to bring suit; by contrast, indirect purchasers further down the supply chain may not bring suit, even if they pay 3 Technically, the Providers’ cause of action is rooted in the Clayton Act, not the Sherman Act. Section 4 of the Clayton Act provides that “any per son who shall be injured in his business or property by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue ... and shall recover threefold the damages by him sustained.” 15 U.S.C. § 15(a). 6 No. 21 1513 higher prices as a result of an upstream defendant’s anticom petitive conduct. Id. at 728–29.4 This court has recognized a conspiracy “exception” to Illi nois Brick, in which plaintiffs who purchase from one member of an antitrust conspiracy may bring suit against any member of the conspiracy. See Paper Sys., Inc. v. Nippon Paper Indus., Co., 281 F.3d 629, 631–32 (7th Cir. 2002).5 In Paper Systems, pa per distributors sued five manufacturers of thermal facsimile paper, alleging that the manufacturers had engaged in a hor izontal price fixing conspiracy among themselves, as well as vertical conspiracies with two trading firms (middlemen). The plaintiffs purchased directly from two of the manufactur ers and indirectly from two other manufacturers via the trad ing firm defendants, so there was no question that the plain tiffs could sue those defendants. A fifth manufacturer, Nip pon Paper, sold its product to distributors who were not al leged to be part of the conspiracy. The court explained that, even though the plaintiffs did not purchase directly from Nip pon, they could sue Nippon under Illinois Brick because Nip pon was allegedly part of the same conspiracy as the four other manufacturers and two trading firms. Paper Systems’ 4 The facts of Illinois Brick offer a useful illustration. There, the State of Illinois sued Illinois Brick, a manufacturer of concrete blocks, alleging that Illinois paid more for the concrete blocks than it would have absent a price fixing conspiracy. Illinois Brick sold the blocks to masonry contrac tors, who sold them to general contractors, who sold their services to the State of Illinois. Because the State had not purchased the blocks directly from Illinois Brick, the State was not the proper party to bring suit. 5 Other circuits have reached the same conclusion. See Insulate SB, Inc. v. Advanced Finishing Sys., Inc., 797 F.3d 538, 542 (8th Cir. 2015); Lowell v. Am. Cyanamid Co., 177 F.3d 1228, 1229–31 (11th Cir. 1999); Arizona v. Shamrock Foods Co., 729 F.2d 1208, 1211–13 (9th Cir. 1984). No. 21 1513 7 interpretation of Illinois Brick reinforces the principle that an titrust liability is joint and several, meaning that each member of a conspiracy may be held liable for all of the damages caused by the conspiracy. Id. Returning to the FAC in this case, the district court incor rectly believed that the conspirator “exception” to the direct purchaser rule was limited to price fixing conspiracies. See Marion Diagnostic Ctr., LLC v. Becton, Dickinson, & Co., No. 18 CV 01059 NJR RJD, 2018 WL 6266751, at *4 (S.D. Ill. Nov. 30, 2018). The FAC alleged that a web of contracts allowed BD to charge supracompetitive prices, not that BD conspired with the distributors and GPOs to fix prices for the Products. Be cause Plaintiffs were not alleging a traditional price fixing conspiracy, and because “[a]pportioning overcharges in this case would lead to the complexities Illinois Brick sought to avoid,” the district court concluded that they were not direct purchasers and therefore could not bring suit against BD. Id. C. Marion I On appeal, this court clarified that the conspiracy “excep tion” to Illinois Brick is not limited to price fixing conspiracies. See Marion I, 952 F.3d at 839. We explained that “it is better to think of the right to sue co conspirators not as an exception to Illinois Brick, but instead as a rule inhering in Illinois Brick that allocates the right to collect 100% of the damages to the first non conspirator in the supply chain.” Id. (citing Paper Sys., 281 F.3d at 631–32). We also observed: “Apple [v. Pepper] confirms that Illinois Brick is a bright line rule allocating the right to sue to direct purchasers alone …. The relationship between the buyer and the seller, rather than the nature of the alleged an ticompetitive conduct, governs whether the buyer may sue under the antitrust laws.” Id. at 840 (citing 139 S. Ct. 1514, 1522 8 No. 21 1513 (2019)). The court concluded that the Providers could sue the distributors under Illinois Brick because the distributors were allegedly conspirators with BD. Marion I, 952 F.3d at 840–41. Turning to the sufficiency of the complaint, however, the Marion I court held that the Providers had failed to allege a plausible hub and spokes conspiracy. Id. at 843. We noted: “The role of the distributors is critical to the Providers’ case. … If the distributors were not part of the alleged conspiracy, then [the] Providers’ case falls apart: no conspiracy, no direct purchaser status, no right to recover.” Id. at 841. To plausibly allege an antitrust conspiracy, the Providers needed to show that “the manufacturer and others had a conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful objec tive.” Id. (emphasis added) (quoting Monsanto Co. v. Spray Rite Serv. Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 768 (1984)). The FAC failed to state a claim because the Providers did not allege that the distributors (the “rim”) coordinated with each other at the direction of BD (the “hub”). Marion I, 952 F.3d at 842–43. Instead, the FAC alleged only that the distrib utors enforced the Net Dealer Contracts between BD and the GPOs and charged a fee for the distributors’ services. The Pro viders did not even allege that the distributors knowingly en gaged in parallel conduct, which could have constituted cir cumstantial evidence of an agreement.6 Id. “All the Providers have alleged is that the distributors buy and sell the devices in accordance with the terms of the contracts that the GPOs 6 Independent action does not violate Section 1 of the Sherman Act. See Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 760; Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 553–54 (2007) (citing Theatre Enters., Inc. v. Paramount Film Distrib. Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 540 (1954)). No. 21 1513 9 have negotiated.” Id. at 843. “They have made no argument that the distributors played any role in setting the anticom petitive pricing or that there was any quid pro quo according to which Becton compensated them for participating in the al leged antitrust conspiracy.” Id. We vacated and remanded so that the Providers could file an amended complaint, “pro vided that they believe they can adequately plead that the dis tributors were part of the putative conspiracy.” Id. D. Dismissal of the SAC On remand, the Providers narrowed their allegations in the SAC to two vertical conspiracies between (1) BD and Car dinal, and (2) BD and McKesson. In other words, the Provid ers dropped their allegations against the GPOs and two other distributors, and the Providers no longer allege a horizontal conspiracy among the remaining distributors. BD, Cardinal, and McKesson all moved to dismiss the SAC for failure to state a claim. The Distributors further argued that the Provid ers lacked Article III standing to sue Cardinal because the Pro viders purchased the Products only from McKesson. The district court agreed with the Defendants and dis missed the case. Marion Diagnostic Ctr., LLC v. Becton, Dickin son & Co., No. 3:18 CV 1059 NJR, 2021 WL 961728 (S.D. Ill. Mar. 15, 2021). Relying on Weit v. Continental Illinois National Bank & Trust Co., 641 F.2d 457 (7th Cir. 1981), the district court concluded that both Article III and Illinois Brick’s direct pur chaser rule require the Providers to show a “sufficient nexus between the defendant’s alleged actions and an injury to plaintiffs.” Id. at 469. The Providers failed to meet this stand ard, in the district court’s view, because any alleged injury from Cardinal’s anticompetitive activity was “vague and ten uous.” Marion Diagnostic Ctr., 2021 WL 961728, at *2. 10 No. 21 1513 Even if the Providers had standing to sue Cardinal, the district court concluded they had failed to allege that BD and the Distributors had “a conscious commitment to a common scheme.” Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 768. The court summarized six key allegations and sorted them into two categories: factors showing quid pro quo, and factors showing conscious com mitment. The court concluded that the following allegations were insufficient to show quid pro quo: the Distributors’ sales staff receive bonuses and other incentives, the Distributors re ceive higher distribution fees, and the Distributors benefit from guaranteed purchasing volume from long term con tracts. These allegations are essentially recycled from the FAC, which this court already held was insufficient to state a claim in Marion I. The district court then concluded that the following alle gations were insufficient to show conscious commitment: BD’s dominant market share facilitates collusion and there are high barriers to entry; the Distributors’ actions are “contrary to their self interest” because they should naturally prefer up stream competition; the Distributors’ contracts with BD in clude agreements to exclude BD’s rivals; the Distributors have the motive to conspire because of BD’s dominance in the mar ket; and the Distributors frequently communicate with BD “beyond what is necessary to merely buy and sell products.” Because the district court concluded that the SAC failed to state a claim, the court did not address Defendants’ related argument that the Providers failed to allege Cardinal or McKesson had market power in the distribution market. The Providers timely appealed. No. 21 1513 11 II. Discussion This court reviews the district court’s dismissal for failure to state a claim de novo. McGarry & McGarry, LLC v. Bankr. Mgmt. Sols., Inc., 937 F.3d 1056, 1062 (7th Cir. 2019). More specifically, we take a fresh look at the district court’s conclusions that the Providers (1) lack standing to sue Cardinal and (2) failed to state a Section 1 conspiracy claim. Id. at 1062–63. A. Standing All agree that the Providers have standing to sue McKesson and BD. The Providers contend that they also have standing to sue Cardinal, even though they did not purchase the Products from Cardinal. Article III limits federal courts’ jurisdiction to “cases” and “controversies.” U.S. Const. art. III, § 2. The “irreducible con stitutional minimum” of standing requires that the plaintiff has “(1) suffered an injury in fact, (2) that is fairly traceable to the challenged conduct of the defendant, and (3) that is likely to be redressed by a favorable judicial decision.” Spokeo, Inc. v. Robins, 136 S. Ct. 1540, 1547 (2016). This court has recog nized that “financial injuries are prototypical of [Article III] injuries,” meaning that paying inflated prices due to an anti competitive scheme will satisfy injury in fact. McGarry & McGarry, 937 F.3d at 1063 (alteration in original); see also Loeb Indus., Inc. v. Sumitomo Corp., 306 F.3d 469, 480–81 (7th Cir. 2002) (“There is no dispute that the plaintiffs in these cases have been injured by paying an inflated price for copper; their Article III standing is therefore secure.”). The Providers argue that the district court “hopelessly confused Article III standing and antitrust ‘standing’ 12 No. 21 1513 doctrine” when it concluded that the Providers lack standing to sue Cardinal. The district court’s opinion did not cite Arti cle III, but it did observe that the “general standing” and “an titrust injury” inquiries “may overlap considerably.” Marion Diagnostic Ctr., 2021 WL 961728, at *2 (citing Weit, 641 F.2d at 469). In Weit, a putative class of credit card holders alleged that five banks were engaged in a horizontal conspiracy to fix credit card interest rates, as well as vertical conspiracies with smaller “correspondent banks.” Weit, 641 F.2d at 459. This court affirmed the district court’s grant of summary judgment in favor of defendants on both the horizontal conspiracy claims and the vertical conspiracy claims. Id. at 466, 468–69. We then addressed whether plaintiffs had standing to assert a vertical conspiracy claim against one bank (Pullman), even though none of the named plaintiffs had Pullman credit cards, because the district court had dismissed Pullman solely for lack of standing. Id. at 469. We cited Illinois Brick in passing for the proposition that plaintiffs must show a direct “anti trust injury,” rather than for the direct purchaser rule.7 Id. 7 Antitrust injury and antitrust standing are related but distinct concepts. The canonical case on antitrust injury is Brunswick v. Pueblo Bowl–O–Mat, not Illinois Brick. See Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl–O–Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 487–89 (1977) (holding that mere economic loss does not amount to an antitrust injury under the antitrust laws). In Brunswick, bowling alley operators alleged that a competitor hurt their businesses by acquiring struggling bowling alleys that otherwise would have gone bankrupt. The Supreme Court rejected their theory of antitrust liability, reiterating that the antitrust laws protect “competition not competitors.” Id. at 488. “The antitrust injury requirement ensures that a plaintiff can recover only if the loss stems from a competition reducing aspect or effect of the defendant’s behavior.” Atl. Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 344 (1990). No. 21 1513 13 Without discussing Article III, the court concluded that plain tiffs were unable to establish a “nexus” between the alleged Pullman conspiracy and any injury to plaintiffs. Id. The district court’s reliance on Weit was admittedly impre cise. The Providers correctly note that Cardinal asked the dis trict court to dismiss on the basis of Article III standing, not antitrust standing. The Distributors respond that the district court properly concluded the Providers’ alleged injury (in flated prices for BD products purchased from McKesson) was not fairly traceable to Cardinal’s alleged conduct (a vertical conspiracy with BD). As explained below, we agree with the Distributors that the Providers lack standing to sue Cardinal under both Article III and Illinois Brick. At the same time, we take this opportunity to clarify the distinction between the two doctrines, even when they point in the same direction. 1. Article III The Providers rely on cases like Loeb Industries, Inc. v. Su mitomo Corp. and Sanner v. Board of Trade of City of Chicago to argue that they have satisfied Article III standing.8 The plain tiffs in Loeb purchased copper on the cash market and alleged that copper merchants and brokers conspired to manipulate the price of copper on the futures market. The court held that plaintiffs had Article III standing to sue, even though the buy ers were not participants in the copper futures market, 8 The Providers also cite McGarry & McGarry, LLC v. Bankruptcy Manage ment Solutions, Inc., 937 F.3d 1056 (7th Cir. 2019), but that case is distin guishable. 937 F.3d 1056, 1063, 1065–66 (7th Cir. 2019) (concluding that plaintiff had “just barely” pleaded sufficient facts for Article III injury in fact, and in any event, plaintiff did not allege the type of injury the anti trust laws were meant to prevent). 14 No. 21 1513 because the defendants’ alleged conduct influenced the price of copper on the cash market. Loeb, 306 F.3d at 480–81. Similarly, in Sanner, a group of soybean farmers alleged that a conspiracy between the Chicago Board of Trade and several individuals had artificially suppressed the price of soybean futures, causing the farmers to sell their soybeans at correspondingly low prices on the cash market. 62 F.3d 918, 921 (7th Cir. 1995). This court held that the farmers had Article III standing because their injury was fairly traceable to the al leged conspiracy. Id. at 924–25, 927–30. As in Loeb, it was irrel evant that the farmers were not participants in the soybean futures market because the conspiracy caused them harm when it came time to sell their soybeans. Id. at 929 (“Since one market tends to move in lockstep with the other, participants in the cash market can be injured by anticompetitive acts com mitted in the futures market.”). We agree that the Providers have sufficiently alleged an injury in fact in the form of higher prices for BD’s products, but they have not shown that their injury is fairly traceable to Cardinal’s conduct. According to the Providers, Loeb and San ner recognize that “a plaintiff has standing simply if it buys products at market prices affected by the defendants’ con duct, even if that conduct occurred in a separate market.” This broad interpretation would eviscerate Illinois Brick’s direct purchaser rule because plaintiffs could always argue that an upstream conspirator’s conduct resulted in higher prices downstream. Moreover, this case is distinguishable from Loeb and San ner because the Providers have not alleged that the price of the three BD Products is readily determinable outside the con text of contract negotiations between the GPOs and BD. No. 21 1513 15 Syringes and catheters are not like soybeans and copper be cause the prices of medical products are not listed on a com modity exchange. The SAC itself alleges that prices vary de pending on terms in the Net Dealer Contracts regarding bun dling, long term discounts, penalty pricing rebate provisions, and so forth. We also note that the Providers cannot “piggy back on the injuries of the unnamed class members” who may have pur chased BD products from Cardinal. Payton v. County of Kane, 308 F.3d 673, 682 (7th Cir. 2002) (“Standing cannot be acquired through the back door of a class action.”); see also TransUnion LLC v. Ramirez, 141 S. Ct. 2190, 2208 (2021) (“Every class mem ber must have Article III standing in order to recover individ ual damages.”).9 2. Direct Purchaser Status In addition to satisfying Article III standing, the Providers must show that they have suffered an antitrust injury and that they are the proper parties to bring suit. We assume for pur poses of this analysis that the Providers have suffered an an titrust injury because they are allegedly paying higher prices for BD’s products than comparable products sold by compet itors.10 The relevant question here is whether the Providers are the proper party to bring suit for that injury. 9 Furthermore, if the litigation were to proceed to the class certification stage, the Providers would not be adequate representatives of medical providers that purchase the Products from Cardinal. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(a)(4). 10 Cf. Chi. Studio Rental, Inc. v. Ill. Dep’t of Commerce, 940 F.3d 971, 978–79 (7th Cir. 2019) (concluding that plaintiff film studio “has pleaded an injury to itself, not an anticompetitive injury to the market”). 16 No. 21 1513 To recap, in Illinois Brick, the Supreme Court held that a direct purchaser from an alleged monopolist or cartel mem ber is the proper party to bring suit; by contrast, indirect pur chasers further down the supply chain may not bring suit, even if they pay higher prices as a result of the defendant’s anticompetitive conduct. 431 U.S. at 729. This court has inter preted Illinois Brick such that a direct purchaser may sue any member of an alleged antitrust conspiracy, so long as the plaintiff is a direct purchaser from at least one member of the conspiracy. See Paper Sys., 281 F.3d at 631–32; Marion I, 952 F.3d at 839. The Providers are direct purchasers from McKesson, which is allegedly in a vertical conspiracy with BD. The prob lem here is that the Providers amended their complaint such that they are no longer alleging a horizontal conspiracy be tween the Distributors. Instead, they now allege two independ ent vertical conspiracies between BD and McKesson, on the one hand, and BD and Cardinal, on the other. Given these al legations, the Providers cannot sue Cardinal under Illinois Brick because the SAC makes clear that they do not purchase BD Products from Cardinal. The Providers claim that they “pay supracompetitive prices for Becton Products whether they buy from Cardinal, McKesson, another distributor, or Becton itself.” But the SAC does not allege that all distributors are in the same conspiracy; rather, the allegations are limited to Cardinal and McKesson, just two of at least four major distributors. This discrepancy is significant because the Providers do not allege that either Car dinal or McKesson has market power in the distribution mar ket. Without market power, it is hard to understand how Car dinal or McKesson would be able to raise prices on BD’s No. 21 1513 17 products without losing business to other distributors. As this court made clear when ruling on the sufficiency of the FAC, “the first buyer from a conspirator is the right party to sue.” Marion I, 952 F.3d at 836 (quoting Paper Sys., 281 F.3d at 631). Because the Providers are no longer alleging a horizontal con spiracy among the Distributors, the so called conspirator ex ception outlined in Paper Systems is inapplicable. Our conclusion aligns with the general principal that anti trust conspiracy liability is joint and several. See Paper Sys., 281 F.3d at 631–32. If Cardinal is not part of the BD McKesson conspiracy, and Plaintiffs are not purchasing the Products from Cardinal, then it does not make sense to hold Cardinal liable, either for the BD McKesson conspiracy or for the BD Cardinal conspiracy. * * * To summarize, the Article III and Illinois Brick inquiries lead to the same outcome in this case: the Providers are not the proper parties to bring suit against Cardinal. But the in quiries remain distinct and serve different purposes. The Pro viders cannot sue Cardinal under Article III because their in jury is not fairly traceable to Cardinal’s conduct. They also cannot sue Cardinal under Illinois Brick, as interpreted by this court in Paper Systems, because they do not purchase the Prod ucts from either member of the BD Cardinal conspiracy. B. Failure to State a Claim Because the Providers lack standing to sue Cardinal, our analysis of the merits focuses on the remaining alleged verti cal conspiracy between BD and McKesson. The district court properly dismissed the SAC for failure to state a claim. We begin with an overview of the legal standards governing 18 No. 21 1513 vertical restraints of trade and then explain why the SAC falls short. 1. Vertical Restraints Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States.” 15 U.S.C. § 1. Courts have long recognized that Section 1 pro hibits only unreasonable restraints of trade. See generally Stand ard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911). Horizontal price fixing agreements between competitors are classic per se vio lations of Section 1, meaning that they are presumed unlaw ful. See, e.g., Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5 (2006). By con trast, vertical restraints are analyzed under the fact specific rule of reason. See Cont’l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 58–59 (1977) (holding that vertical nonprice restraints are subject to the rule of reason); Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 882 (2007) (holding that vertical price restraints, including minimum resale prices, are subject to the rule of reason). Under the rule of reason, “the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive prac tice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable re straint on competition.” GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 49. Relevant factors include the restraint’s history, nature, and effect; spe cific information about the relevant business; and whether the businesses involved have market power.11 The purpose of the 11 See, e.g., Copperweld Corp. v. Indep. Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 768 (1984) (equating the rule of reason with “an inquiry into market power and market structure designed to assess [a restraint’s] actual effect”); Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 45–46 (2006) (holding that plaintiffs alleging antitrust violation from tying arrangements involving a No. 21 1513 19 rule is to distinguish “between restraints with anticompetitive effect that are harmful to the consumer and restraints stimu lating competition that are in the consumer’s best interest.” Leegin, 551 U.S. at 886. Before this court can even apply the rule of reason analy sis, it needs to resolve the threshold question whether the SAC sufficiently alleges a vertical conspiracy between BD and McKesson. In Monsanto Co. v. Spray Rite Service Corp., the Su preme Court announced the following standard of proof for vertical conspiracies: “there must be direct or circumstantial evidence that reasonably tends to prove that the manufac turer and others had a conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful objective.” 465 U.S. 752, 768 (1984) (emphasis added). Two features of Monsanto complicate its applicability to this case. First, the Monsanto court was reviewing a jury verdict, so the Court did not opine on the kinds of allegations necessary to state a claim. Second, at the time that Monsanto was decided, vertical price fixing (also referred to as resale price maintenance) was still per se illegal. Today, the same conduct would be evaluated under the rule of reason. See Leegin, 551 U.S. at 882 (overruling Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911)). That being said, some language in Monsanto remains use ful for analyzing the sufficiency of the SAC. In particular, the Court noted: “[T]he fact that a manufacturer and its distribu tors are in constant communication about prices and market ing strategy does not alone show that the distributors are not making independent pricing decisions. A manufacturer and patented product must prove that a defendant has market power in the tying product). 20 No. 21 1513 its distributors have legitimate reasons to exchange infor mation about the prices and the reception of their products in the market.” Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 762. “Moreover, distribu tors are an important source of information for manufactur ers. In order to assure an efficient distribution system, manu facturers and distributors constantly must coordinate their ac tivities to assure that their product will reach the consumer persuasively and efficiently.” Id. at 763–64. These passages suggest that the Providers’ allegations regarding the Distrib utors’ frequent communications with BD are not necessarily indicative of collusion. 2. The SAC To survive a motion to dismiss, a complaint must “state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.” Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 570 (2007); see Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(a)(2). We accept the factual allegations in the SAC as true and draw all permissible inferences in favor of the Providers. Viamedia, Inc. v. Comcast Corp., 951 F.3d 429, 454 (7th Cir. 2020). To state a Section 1 claim, a plaintiff must allege that the defendant “(1) entered into an agreement that (2) unreasonably restrains trade in the relevant market and (3) caused the plaintiff an an titrust injury.” Ass’n of Am. Physicians & Surgeons, Inc. v. Am. Bd. of Med. Specialties, 15 F.4th 831, 833 (7th Cir. 2021). The Providers contend that the district court was wrong to separate their allegations into two groups: allegations tending to show a “conscious commitment,” and allegations tending to show quid pro quo. They argue that the district court should have considered the SAC as a whole, and that doing so would have led it to a different conclusion. The Providers’ fixation on the two categories of allegations is a red herring. No. 21 1513 21 The real question is whether the Providers’ new allegations fare any better than those in the FAC. Many of the Providers’ allegations are “recycled,” and we already deemed those allegations insufficient in Marion I. The Providers’ allegations regarding BD’s “other anticompetitive acts,” for example, are essentially unchanged from the FAC. Similarly, allegations regarding BD’s “rewards to the distrib utors,” now offered as evidence of a quid pro quo, appeared elsewhere in the FAC. The Providers previously alleged that: (1) the fees distributors receive are tied to prices paid for BD products (as negotiated with GPOs in the Net Dealer Con tracts), (2) BD pays higher commissions to distributors than its rival manufacturers, and (3) long term contracts provide distributors with guaranteed purchasing volume. Those alle gations also appear in SAC. The Providers point to additional details in the SAC, in cluding allegations that the Distributors receive not only com missions, but also bonuses, gifts, vacations, and other perks, thereby reducing the Distributors’ labor costs. We are skepti cal that these incentives constitute sufficient circumstantial evidence of a conspiracy, particularly because the incentives are directed to frontline sales representatives. To participate in a conspiracy, agents of a defendant must have “knowledge of the principal’s unlawful objective” and “an intent to re strain trade.” Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Anti trust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Applica tion ¶ 1474c (last updated Sept. 2021); see also id. (“The broker who merely earns its commission … does not share a ‘con scious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful objective.’” (quoting Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764)). The SAC is silent on whether the Distributors’ sales 22 No. 21 1513 representatives knew of any conspiracy, much less shared an intent to participate in one. The Providers added the following “new” allegations in the SAC: that the Distributors go beyond their contractual ob ligations by cutting off lines of credit, increasing delivery fees, embedding sales staff with providers to monitor compliance with exclusive dealing terms, and providing purchasing his tory to BD but not to other manufacturers. It is “conceivable” that McKesson took steps along these lines to encourage pro viders to buy BD products. Twombly, 550 U.S. at 570. But as the Defendants argue, those steps are just as consistent with the Distributors’ rational, lawful self interest in encouraging sales with a leading manufacturer. See id. at 554. The primary obstacle for the Providers is that they have narrowed their allegations from a hub and spokes conspiracy to two vertical conspiracies. The Providers have also dropped their allegations against two other distributors and the GPOs. In other words, they now need to show that vertical conspir acies involving just two distributors and BD could plausibly influence the prices that the Providers pay for the Products, regardless of which distributor they purchase from, and re gardless of the fact that there are at least four major distribu tors. In our view, this is simply not plausible. The Providers have not included any allegations showing that McKesson is unique in its attempts to encourage sales of BD products, or that the benefits McKesson receives from selling BD products differ from the benefits any other distributor would receive.12 12 The only Cardinal specific allegation is that Cardinal promotes BD’s products over those of its in house brand, Covidien. This allegation alone No. 21 1513 23 If other distributors receive the same benefits but are not al leged to be conspiring with BD, then there is no basis to infer the existence of a conspiracy between McKesson and BD. The Distributors are also not involved in negotiating prices for BD products in the Net Dealer Contracts—those ne gotiations are solely between BD and the GPOs. The Distrib utors benefit from a percentage markup of those prices if and only if providers decide to purchase BD’s products from a particular distributor. In that way, all distributors benefit in directly from marketing BD products to providers because they will make more money than if they sell another manu facturer’s products. That does not mean, however, that McKesson is conspiring with BD to raise prices. See Marion I, 952 F.3d at 839 (“[T]he manufacturer has an incentive to get the best deal it can from its distributors, both in terms of price and in terms of necessary services. … The manufacturer’s in terests thus align with those of the consumer who buys from the distributor, not with those of the distributor.”). Moreover, the Providers have not convincingly explained why they can not choose distributors who are not alleged to be conspiring with BD. The Providers cite Twombly’s plausibility standard repeat edly, but the outcome in that case cuts against them. Twombly demonstrates that courts should dismiss antitrust conspiracy complaints for failure to state a claim when the allegations, taken as true, could just as easily reflect innocent conduct or rational self interest. See Twombly, 550 U.S. at 554 (noting that parallel conduct is “consistent with conspiracy, but just as is insufficient to move the needle, and more importantly, the Providers lack standing to sue Cardinal. 24 No. 21 1513 much in line with a wide swath of rational and competitive business strategy unilaterally prompted by common percep tions of the market”). Because the Providers have not plausi bly alleged a vertical conspiracy between BD and McKesson, we affirm the district court’s decision on that basis. The district court declined to reach the Distributors’ alternative basis for dismissal—that the Providers failed to allege Cardinal or McKesson has market power in the distribution market. In light of our conclusion that the SAC fails to state a claim, we decline to address this argument in the first instance. III. Conclusion For the foregoing reasons, the district court’s grant of the motion to dismiss is AFFIRMED.
Primary Holding

Seventh Circuit rejects a purported class action by medical providers, alleging antitrust violations arising from a conspiracy to drive up the prices of medical products.


Disclaimer: Justia Annotations is a forum for attorneys to summarize, comment on, and analyze case law published on our site. Justia makes no guarantees or warranties that the annotations are accurate or reflect the current state of law, and no annotation is intended to be, nor should it be construed as, legal advice. Contacting Justia or any attorney through this site, via web form, email, or otherwise, does not create an attorney-client relationship.

Some case metadata and case summaries were written with the help of AI, which can produce inaccuracies. You should read the full case before relying on it for legal research purposes.

This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.