Bay Guardian v. New Times Media

Annotate this Case
Download PDF
Filed 8/11/10 CERTIFIED FOR PARTIAL PUBLICATION* IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT DIVISION ONE BAY GUARDIAN COMPANY, Plaintiff and Respondent, v. A122448 NEW TIMES MEDIA LLC et al., Defendants and Appellants. (Super. Ct. for the City & County of San Francisco No. CGC-04-435584) The Bay Guardian and the San Francisco Weekly are competing alternative newspapers in the San Francisco Bay Area. Each paper relies on advertising revenue in large part to sustain the publication of the news weekly. San Francisco Weekly offered advertising to business entities at a rate lower than was provided by the Bay Guardian. Consequently, the Bay Guardian sued San Francisco Weekly for unfair competition under California law. It was successful and won a jury verdict of approximately $16 million. This appeal has been taken by defendants New Times Media (the New Times), San Francisco Weekly (the SF Weekly), and East Bay Express (the Express), from a judgment that awarded plaintiff Bay Area Guardian (the Guardian) damages in an action for violations of Business and Professions Code section 17043 based on sales of advertising at rates below cost for the purpose of harming a competitor.1 Defendants * Pursuant to California Rules of Court, rules 8.1105(b) and 8.1110, this opinion is certified for publication with the exception of parts IV and V of the Discussion. 1 All further statutory references are to the Business and Professions Code unless otherwise indicated. claim that the trial court erred by failing to admit defense evidence and properly instruct the jury on the essential element in a section 17043 action of proof of the defendant s ability to recoup losses. Defendants also argue that the court gave defective instructions on the intent or purpose to harm a competitor and the statutory presumption of improper purpose stated in section 17071. They further assert that the evidence presented by plaintiff failed to adequately prove the element of damages caused by the below-cost sales, or that the New Times and the Express were agents of the SF Weekly so as to incur liability to plaintiff pursuant to section 17095. We conclude that recoupment of losses by the defendant is not a requirement to prove a violation of section 17043. Therefore, the trial court did not err by failing to instruct the jury on recoupment of losses as an element of the action, by limiting the presentation of defense evidence on recoupment, or by denying defendants motions for judgment based on lack of evidence of recoupment. We also conclude that the court s instructions on the purpose to harm a competitor and the statutory presumption of improper purpose were not erroneous. Substantial evidence supports the finding of damages suffered by plaintiff, and the agency relationship between the SF Weekly and the New Times. The judgment against the Express must be reversed for lack of evidence that it acted as an agent of the SF Weekly to sell advertising at rates below cost in violation of section 17043. Otherwise, we affirm the judgment.2 2 Following oral argument and submission of the case (Cal. Rules of Court, rule 8.256(d)(1)), the parties notified us that a settlement in the matter has been reached pursuant to Code of Civil Procedure section 664.6, although they have not as yet filed a stipulation for dismissal of the proceedings. Settlement of the case of course renders the appeal moot, but does not require that we dismiss the appeal. (Fox Searchlight Pictures, Inc. v. Paladino (2001) 89 Cal.App.4th 294, 300, fn. 4 [106 Cal.Rptr.2d 906]; Lucich v. City of Oakland (1993) 19 Cal.App.4th 494, 502 [23 Cal.Rptr.2d 450]; In re Marriage of Dade (1991) 230 Cal.App.3d 621, 627 [281 Cal.Rptr. 609]; Eisenberg, et al., Cal. Practice Guide: Civil Appeals and Writs (The Rutter Group 2009) ¶¶ 5:64, 6:125.1.) Dismissal of the action at this extraordinarily late stage of the proceedings based on settlement or stipulation of the parties is discretionary rather than mandatory. (City of Morgan Hill v. Brown (1999) 71 Cal.App.4th 1114, 1121, fn. 5 [84 Cal.Rptr.2d 361].) Because this action presents issues of continuing public interest which are likely to recur, we exercise our inherent discretion to resolve those issues despite the settlement. (Cadence Design Systems, Inc. v. Avant! Corp. (2002) 29 Cal.4th 215, 218, fn. 2 [127 Cal.Rptr.2d 169, 57 P.3d 647]; Liberty Mut. Ins. Co. v. Fales (1973) 8 Cal.3d 712, 715 716 [106 Cal.Rptr. 21, 505 P.2d 213]; Castro v. STATEMENT OF FACTS The Guardian was first published in October of 1966 in San Francisco as an alternative newspaper of tabloid size, published weekly and distributed free of charge. The Guardian targeted a young, educated, affluent audience, more focused on alternative views and life styles than daily newspapers such as the San Francisco Chronicle or San Francisco Examiner. Without any revenue from circulation, the Guardian relied almost exclusively on sale of advertising space in the paper to produce income. The Guardian sold two forms of advertising: classified advertising, which was primarily personal in nature and was placed in the back of the paper; and display advertising, which was purchased by local retail businesses and sold modularly as a larger portion of a page of the newspaper. During the first six years of existence the Guardian struggled, and was published only irregularly. By 1995, however, the Guardian became the dominant weekly newspaper in the San Francisco Bay Area. Between 1985 to 1995, revenues grew from $2 million to $8 million, and then to over $11 million by 2000, of which $7.6 million was attributable to display advertising. Over the years the Guardian did not compete with the radio or even the daily newspapers, but rather with other non-daily papers which also had alternative editorial content. One of the Guardian s competitors was defendant SF Weekly, which in 1995 principally focused on the music scene in San Francisco, and had a target demographic of 18 to 40 years of age. Defendant the New Times decided to acquire the SF Weekly in 1995 to enter the vibrant San Francisco journalism market. At the time the SF Weekly was a marginally profitable newspaper of under 70 pages per edition which had a circulation of about Superior Court (2004) 116 Cal.App.4th 1010, 1014, fn. 3 [10 Cal.Rptr.3d 865]; Black Diamond Asphalt, Inc. v. Superior Court (2003) 114 Cal.App.4th 109, 115 [7 Cal.Rptr.3d 466]; Rosales v. Thermex-Thermatron, Inc. (1998) 67 Cal.App.4th 187, 191, fn. 1 [78 Cal.Rptr.2d 861].) Additionally, this court consulted the parties regarding the possible partial publication of the decision in this case. The court has received written reply from counsel for the parties that both sides agree the publication of an opinion in this case is appropriate under California Rules of Court, rules 8.1110(c). 90,000 about half that of the Guardian. The objective of the acquisition of SF Weekly was to increase circulation and improve content by bringing more magazine-length journalism into the paper. Thus, from 1995 to 2000 the journalism staff of the SF Weekly was increased significantly, as was the editorial size of the paper, its circulation, number of advertisers, and total revenue. The Guardian adduced evidence at trial that soon after the acquisition the executive editor of the New Times, Mike Lacey, disparaged the content of both the SF Weekly and the Guardian at a staff meeting, and announced that he wanted the SF Weekly to be the only game in town. The Guardian was considered the primary competitor of the SF Weekly. Lacey stressed that the New Times had deep pockets, with the financial resources to compete very aggressively with the Guardian and use guerilla tactics in rate battles. Lacey also emphasized that he was interested in improving the editorial quality of the SF Weekly. To increase circulation, additional salaried journalists were hired to bring higher quality long form journalism to the paper. The essence of Lacey s message was that he wanted to put the Bay Guardian out of business. One of the new policies implemented at the SF Weekly was to specifically target businesses which advertised in the Guardian. The previous advertising policy of the SF Weekly, like that of the Guardian, was to set the advertising rate card based on the overhead costs of publishing the newspaper, plus a variable percentage, depending on the frequency of the customer s advertising. Rates were structured on a graduated frequency discount scale, with customers who advertised 52 weeks throughout the year offered a lower rate than a one time customer. Ads were sold according to the frequency earned. Following the acquisition of the SF Weekly by the New Times, sales representatives were authorized to directly contact advertisers in the Guardian and offer to sell advertising at a lower frequency than was earned to transfer their business to the SF Weekly. The sales representatives were made aware that advertising could be sold below cost if needed in order to make a sale, and the resources of the New Times would cover the losses, even over a term of many years. For example, the SF Weekly began to offer Bay Guardian advertisers the rate for 52 times, even if the advertiser only agreed to run for one week. Furthermore the SF Weekly identified key categories of advertising emphasis in the newspaper, such as restaurants, fitness clubs, health and beauty, music and film, and furniture. To increase volume in those categories, the strategy of SF Weekly was to initially lower the [introductory] rate to advertisers to build up a certain amount of critical mass, then once volume was established slowly increase the rates over time of both the re-signs and new advertisers. The Guardian recognized that SF Weekly had become a threatening competitor, along with internet publishing. Both newspapers appealed to essentially the same demographic and attracted many of the same advertisers. Competition between the two newspapers for advertisers was pretty intense. The fundamental objective of the Guardian was essentially the same as the SF Weekly: to become dominant in the San Francisco marketplace. In March of 2001, the New Times acquired another alternative weekly newspaper, the Express, which then had a circulation of about 60,000 to 65,000. The Express, which was based in Oakland, offered advertising customers a slightly different geographical region of exposure than the Guardian or the SF Weekly, and in conjunction with the SF Weekly provided a greater coverage area and circulation than the Guardian alone. As with the SF Weekly, the approach of the New Times was to improve the editorial quality of the Express and increase circulation. The Express provided reduced rates to advertising customers, which it intended to slowly raise over time. Despite its lower circulation the Express charged higher advertising rates than the SF Weekly, although lower rates than the Guardian. Once the Express was acquired by the New Times, to entice prospective advertisers away from the Guardian the SF Weekly also offered free advertisements in the Express. The New Times anticipated losses at the Express while the paper was developed and expanded. Thereafter, through 2007, the SF Weekly and the Express continued to offer advertising, particularly to advertisers in key categories, at rates at least 20 percent below those charged by the Guardian, below the rate card prices, and well below its own costs per inch of display advertising space. According to the calculations of plaintiff s expert, the SF Weekly s average advertising space costs ranged from $21 per inch in 2001 to $29 per inch in 2007, whereas the average sale price of advertising space varied from $17 per inch in 2002 to $20 per inch in 2007. For the same time period, the Guardian s advertising costs per inch of paper ranged from nearly $23 in 2001, to $18 in 2004, and $20 in 2007; its display revenue per inch was nearly $23 in 2001, $18 in 2004, and nearly $22 in 2007. As a result of reduced-price advertising offered by the SF Weekly, the Guardian consistently lost other advertising customers and revenue to the SF Weekly after 1995, even though the Guardian had 20 percent greater distribution in San Francisco and therefore theoretically should have received a 20 percent greater price for advertising. An examination of customer account ledgers for 128 customers and over 20,000 advertising transactions with the Guardian and the two New Times papers between 1999 and the first quarter of 2007 revealed that 91 percent of the transactions of the SF Weekly and Express were sold below cost. For approximately 66.5 percent of those transactions the Guardian either lost customers to defendants papers or was compelled to discount advertising rates to remain competitive. As an illustration, by offering reduced rates to advertisers the SF Weekly managed to obtain the critical print advertising account of Bill Graham Presents (BGP), a major concert producer which historically advertised heavily in the Guardian.3 After the acquisition by the New Times, BGP consolidated more of its advertising budget with the SF Weekly, 75 to 80 percent, at favorable, below-cost rates, while at the same time reducing its overall print promotion in favor of radio and online advertising. Then in 3 BGP as an independent concert promoter became part of Live Nation, a large conglomerate of entertainment entities. 2005, BGP entered into a sponsorship agreement to direct to the SF Weekly a minimum annual display advertising purchase of $350,000 or 90 percent of its advertising budget in alternative newspaper publications in the Bay Area market, whichever was greater.4 In exchange, the SF Weekly paid an annual sponsorship fee to BGP for naming rights to the Warfield Theatre owned by BGP, and was given exclusive advertising rights associated with that venue. The advertising prices charged to BGP by the SF Weekly under the sponsorship agreement were above previous rates, but still below cost. Before the sponsorship agreement, BGP spent approximately $160,000 per year in advertising with the Guardian. As a result of the agreement between BGP and the SF Weekly, the Guardian subsequently received only a fraction of its previous advertising revenue from BGP, and lost hundreds of thousands of advertising dollars. In 2004, the Guardian began a program to match the SF Weekly s lower advertising prices to some customers on a case by case basis by giving discounts, free ads and upsizes in the paper. The program lasted two or three years, but did not appreciably abate the Guardian s revenue losses. Between 2000 and 2007 the Guardian suffered a loss of display advertising revenue of about 50 percent, and earned a total profit of $1.2 million. The Guardian and the SF Weekly also lost advertising revenue, particularly classified business, to internet providers such as Craigslist, which attracted the youthful demographic targeted by both papers. The dot com bust in the San Francisco Bay Area in 2001 further caused appreciable loss of display advertising revenues for both papers, as did the ensuing more general recession. The Guardian increased advertising revenues between 1996 and 2000, but suffered substantial loss of income between 2000 and 2007.5 4 The annual amount was subsequently reduced from $350,000 to $330,000. The agreement also gave BGP discretion to allocate the annual minimum print placement to SF Weekly or the Express. 5 Display advertising revenue figures for the SF Weekly and the Guardian, respectively, were as follows: $1.76 and $5.48 million in 1996; $5.25 and $7.84 million in 2000; and $4.32 and $4.51 million in 2007. Despite increases in circulation and advertising revenue, between 1995 and 2007 the editorial expenses for the SF Weekly and the Express increased dramatically, and with the exception of 2000 and 2001 the papers lost money every year that the New Times parent company was forced to cover. The New Times sold the Express in 2007, due to lack of progress financially, for much less than the acquisition price six years earlier. Plaintiff offered expert opinion testimony from CPA Clifford Kupperberg, presenting an analysis of damages suffered by the Guardian as a result of defendant s advertising price structure. Kupperberg suggested several models for calculation of plaintiff s damages, which he characterized as the revenue or profits the Guardian would have earned during the damage period established by the court the fiscal years 2001 through 2007 but for defendants below-cost advertising. Kupperberg acknowledged that a damage analysis of something that didn t happen can never be perfect, but through his methodology of examining comparable situations he attempted to discern the most reasonable measure of damages. In one model Kupperberg assumed that between 2001 and 2007 the Guardian would have continued to charge the same rate for advertising space that is, $2,270 per page as it had for the five years (1996 to 2001) before the below-cost pricing damage event. The total amount of damages according to this model, without any increase in advertising volume, was $4,856,000. A different comparable model approach took into account an increase in the Guardian s display revenue achievement in the damages period at a rate or percentage equivalent to the two other most comparable Bay Area weekly newspapers (the Bay weeklies) those being the Palo Alto Weekly and the Pacific Sun or alternative newspapers operated elsewhere by the New Times (the New Times weeklies), that were not impacted by the SF Weekly s pricing structure. Those projected profits were then compared to the actual expenditures, profits and losses of the Guardian during the same damages period. As so calculated the total projected damages ranged from a low of $7.3 million as measured by the Bay Weeklies to a high of $10.2 million as measured by the New Times weeklies. Kupperberg also calculated damages according to a minimum change model, based on a projection that the Guardian would not have lost any net market share to the SF Weekly during the damages period in the absence of below-cost pricing. Assuming the Guardian maintained its revenues for the damages period, the total calculated damages were between $4 and $5.2 million. Kupperberg felt that the minimum change model did not give a complete picture of the loss because it was not adjusted for the higher prices the Guardian could have charged for the lost sales without the unfair practices. The calculation of damages under Kupperberg s models ranged from a low of $4,083,748 to a high of $11,834,570.6 Kupperberg asserted that all of the models he mentioned, although imperfect, could be representative of what happened, but the most appropriate method of calculation depended on the jury s view of the facts. He also testified that a calculation of damages based on an examination of individual transactions was both impractical due to the hundreds of thousands of transactions at issue and inaccurate given the impossibility of knowing which transactions would have gone to [the] Bay Guardian absent the [be]low-cost pricing. Defendants countered with expert opinion testimony by accountant Everett Harry that Kupperberg s models were based on faulty assumptions as to potential earnings during the damages period, and failed to follow established accounting guidelines for certainty. Harry formed the opinion that Kupperberg s models and ultimate analysis of damages were unreasonable, unsupported based upon speculation and completely exaggerated. The range of Kupperberg s damage estimates, asserted Harry, is far too wide to pass a reasonableness test. Harry testified that the evidence of damages 6 In his prior deposition Kupperberg reached a different calculation of the Guardian s lost revenues during the damages period based on use of statistics from the Association of Alternative Newspapers. Before trial Kupperberg repudiated his prior method of calculation because he decided it was based on lack of comparable information. presented by plaintiff failed to consider competition for advertising from the internet, direct mail advertising, other free newspapers such as the San Francisco Examiner, and entertainment inserts in the San Francisco Chronicle. He also considered the cost plus six percent revenue model used by Kupperberg for calculating damages unreasonable, as based on an erroneous assumption of a price per page for display advertising that the Guardian could not have continued to charge during the damages period. Defendants also presented expert opinion testimony to prove that the SF Weekly was not seeking to harm the Guardian as a competitor with its advertising pricing scheme. Economics Professor Joseph Kalt testified that below-cost pricing by the SF Weekly for the purpose of injuring competition would not make sense from a business or economic point of view. Kalt reasoned that the SF Weekly possessed neither the market power to control the alternative newspaper market and drive out competition, nor the protection from competitors to ultimately raise prices and recover the losses, both of which are required to make below-cost pricing a rational, sensible act from a business perspective. Kalt examined the economic data and market trends, including increased internet competition, and found that the SF Weekly failed to increase its revenues from below-cost pricing or drive the Guardian and other competition from the market. In rebuttal, plaintiff presented evidence that corroborated the essential enduring profitability of weekly alternative newspapers in the Bay Area during the damages period, in the form of testimony from William Johnson, who published the two Bay Weeklies the Palo Alto Weekly and the Pacific Sun used as comparables in Kupperberg s model. Many of the advertisers in the Guardian and the SF Weekly also advertise concurrently in these two Bay Weeklies. Johnson testified that the damage analysis by Kupperberg properly compared the Guardian and the SF Weekly with the Bay Weeklies he published in terms of content, circulation, marketing strategies and advertising revenues. He added that the New Times weeklies, with the exception of geography, were also quite comparable to the Guardian and the SF Weekly. Johnson offered the opinion that the revenue and profit figures given by Kupperberg were correct. According to Johnson, the alternative weekly newspapers did not suffer from the business downturn during the damages period or the increase in internet advertising in the same way as did daily newspapers. He testified that the relocation of advertising revenues from the daily newspapers to the internet has not occurred to any appreciable degree with non-daily newspapers.7 Johnson observed no impact on any of his papers from internet advertising. Both the Palo Alto Weekly and the Pacific Sun, which were not affected by the SF Weekly s below-cost advertising, realized an average gradual increase in display advertising revenues and profits during the damages period.8 Johnson further testified that an offer by a competitor of advertising rates below the rate card has a very large impact on pricing and advertising revenue. At the conclusion of trial, the jury found that defendants sold advertising space at a price below cost for the purpose of harming plaintiff as a competitor in violation of section 17043. A verdict was rendered in favor of plaintiff and against each of the defendants in the total amount of $15,923,521.82 that is, $6,395,636 in actual damages suffered by plaintiff, partially trebled, plus prejudgment interest. This appeal followed. DISCUSSION I. The Element of Recoupment of Losses. Defendants argue that a series of errors were committed by the trial court, due to the court s failure to recognize that a defendant s ability to recoup losses following below-cost pricing is an essential element of proof of a violation of section 17043. Referring to parallel federal and state predatory pricing laws, defendants maintain that an objectively reasonable probability of recouping losses through later monopoly pricing must be established by the plaintiff in a section 17043 action. The trial court denied defendants motion for summary judgment, partially excluded proffered defense 7 The reason, suggested Johnson, is that the editorial content of weekly newspapers is quite different and more localized than the daily papers, and advertisers have no other place to go, including the internet, to reach the audience of the alternative weeklies. 8 The Pacific Sun was purchased by Johnson in 2004, and became profitable by 2007. evidence on recoupment, denied motions for directed verdict, refused to give a recoupment instruction proposed by the defense, gave the plaintiff s instruction that no proof the defendant would have had a reasonable expectation of recouping its losses by eliminating the plaintiff as a competitor was necessary,9 and finally denied a motion for judgment notwithstanding the verdict, all predicated upon a faulty determination that California law does not require proof of recoupment ability. Defendants claim that in its rulings the court failed to assess whether recoupment ability existed and compounded that error by instructing that the jury was not required to find that defendants conduct was economically rational or that defendants would likely be able to recoup losses from below-cost sales. They also point out that without any proof of recoupment ability presented by plaintiff, we must reverse and direct judgment for defendants. The issue of recoupment ability as an element of an action for below-cost pricing under the Unfair Practices Act (§ 17200 et seq. (the UPA))10 has not yet been resolved, and requires that we undertake an interpretation of section 17043. In interpreting this statute, our goal is to determine the intent of the Legislature and thereby effectuate the purpose of the law. [Citation.] To do so, we apply certain fundamental rules of statutory interpretation. Our first step [in determining the Legislature s intent] is to scrutinize the actual words of the statute, giving them a plain and commonsense meaning. [Citations.] [Citations.] (Colgan v. Leatherman Tool Group, Inc. (2006) 135 9 Defendants proposed instruction No. 35 refused by the court was: In order to recover, plaintiff must show that defendants had the motive to sell advertising below cost for the purpose and desire of injuring competitors or destroying competition, and also that they had the purpose and ability to recover any of their own lost profits after they have driven the plaintiff out of the market. In full, plaintiff s instruction given by the court was: Plaintiff need not prove that it was economically rational for any defendant to act with the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition, or that a defendant would have had a reasonable expectation of recouping its losses by eliminating the plaintiff as a competitor. However, such evidence may be considered to the extent that it is relevant to a defendant s purpose. 10 The Unfair Practices Act has also been called the Unfair Business Practices Act and the Unfair Competition Act. (See Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. Los Angeles Cellular Telephone Co. (1999) 20 Cal.4th 163, 168 169 [83 Cal.Rptr.2d 548, 973 P.2d 527]; Bank of the West v. Superior Court (1992) 2 Cal.4th 1254, 1258 [10 Cal.Rptr.2d 538, 833 P.2d 545]; Klein v. Earth Elements, Inc. (1997) 59 Cal.App.4th 965, 968 [69 Cal.Rptr.2d 623].) We will refer to it as The Unfair Practices Act, or in short as the UPA. Cal.App.4th 663, 683 [38 Cal.Rptr.3d 36].) We reject an interpretation that would render particular terms mere surplusage, and instead seek to give significance to every word. (City of San Jose v. Superior Court (1993) 5 Cal.4th 47, 55 [19 Cal.Rptr.2d 73, 850 P.2d 621].) When the language of a statute is clear, we need go no further. However, when the language is susceptible of more than one reasonable interpretation, we look to a variety of extrinsic aids, including the ostensible objects to be achieved, the evils to be remedied, the legislative history, public policy, contemporaneous administrative construction, and the statutory scheme of which the statute is a part. (Nolan v. City of Anaheim (2004) 33 Cal.4th 335, 340 [14 Cal.Rptr.3d 857, 92 P.3d 350].) We commence our examination of section 17043 by observing the obvious: the language of the statute does not expressly mention recoupment in any way. Section 17043 provides: It is unlawful for any person engaged in business within this State to sell any article or product at less than the cost thereof to such vendor, or to give away any article or product, for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition. Under section 17071, proof of one or more acts of selling or giving away any article or product below cost or at discriminatory prices, together with proof of the injurious effect of such acts, is presumptive evidence of the purpose or intent to injure competitors or destroy competition. Recoupment is nowhere referred to in the governing statutes. Established law has also not specified that ability to recoup losses is an element of the statutory prohibition. To prove a violation of section 17043, the cases have declared that a plaintiff must allege and prove two elements: below-cost sales undertaken for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition, that has resulted in a competitive injury. (Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. Los Angeles Cellular Telephone Co., supra, 20 Cal.4th 163, 175; Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court (2003) 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 330 [7 Cal.Rptr.3d 628]; Turnbull & Turnbull v. ARA Transportation, Inc. (1990) 219 Cal.App.3d 811, 819 820 [268 Cal.Rptr. 856].) Thus, as defendants recognize, recoupment as an element of the statutory cause of action must be added to section 17043 by necessary implication from its consumerwelfare purpose. We do not lightly imply terms or requirements that have not been expressly included in a statute. (People v. Gardeley (1996) 14 Cal.4th 605, 622 [59 Cal.Rptr.2d 356, 927 P.2d 713]; Alpha Mechanical, Heating & Air Conditioning, Inc. v. Travelers Casualty & Surety Co. of America (2005) 133 Cal.App.4th 1319, 1340 [35 Cal.Rptr.3d 496].) [A]n intention to legislate by implication is not to be presumed. [Citation.] (Citizens for Better Streets v. Board of Supervisors (2004) 117 Cal.App.4th 1, 6 [11 Cal.Rptr.3d 349].) The courts are not authorized to insert provisions or rewrite a statute to conform to an assumed intention which does not appear from its language. (Stop Youth Addiction, Inc. v. Lucky Stores, Inc. (1998) 17 Cal.4th 553, 573 [71 Cal.Rptr.2d 731, 950 P.2d 1086]; Lewco Iron Metals, Inc. v. Superior Court (1999) 76 Cal.App.4th 837, 843 [90 Cal.Rptr.2d 671].) Defendants argument for an implied recoupment provision rests on federal laws, particularly the Robinson-Patman Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 13, 21) and section 2 of the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. § 2), along with predatory pricing laws enacted by other states. We have no dispute with the first part of defendants premise that in predatory pricing actions pursued under federal law and some states, two prerequisites to recovery must be proved by the plaintiff: first, a rival s low prices are below an appropriate measure of its rival s costs; and second, the defendant had a reasonable prospect or dangerous probability of recouping its investment in below-cost prices. (Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. (1993) 509 U.S. 209, 222, 224 [125 L.Ed.2d 168, 113 S.Ct. 2578]; Vollrath Co. v. Sammi Corp. (9th Cir. 1993) 9 F.3d 1455, 1463.) The United States Supreme Court has declared: For the investment to be rational, the [predator] must have a reasonable expectation of recovering, in the form of later monopoly profits, more than the losses suffered. [Citation.] Recoupment is the ultimate object of an unlawful predatory pricing scheme; it is the means by which a predator profits from predation. Without it, predatory pricing produces lower aggregate prices in the market, and consumer welfare is enhanced. Although unsuccessful predatory pricing may encourage some inefficient substitution toward the product being sold at less than its cost, unsuccessful predation is in general a boon to consumers. [¶] . . . [¶] For recoupment to occur, below-cost pricing must be capable, as a threshold matter, of producing the intended effects on the firm s rivals, whether driving them from the market, or . . . causing them to raise their prices to supracompetitive levels within a disciplined oligopoly. (Brooke Group Ltd., supra, at pp. 224 225.) Where we find fault with defendants argument is in the assertion that section 17043 is entirely analogous to the federal and sister-state predatory pricing laws, and must therefore be interpreted correspondingly. Section 17043 recites distinctive language, and has dissimilar elements and a different focus than defendants proffered statutory counterparts. The predatory pricing statutes referred to by defendants may all prohibit discriminatory or below-cost pricing, but the federal and other-state predatory pricing laws, unlike section 17043, do not include an intent requirement. (A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc. (7th Cir. 1989) 881 F.2d 1396, 1401 1402.) The federal law instead looks to the ultimate monopolistic impact and threatened harm produced by the pricing scheme that is, the probability of recoupment through future supracompetitive pricing upon elimination of competitors.11 (See Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., supra, 509 U.S. 209, 224 225; Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc. (1986) 479 U.S. 104, 117 118 [93 L.Ed.2d 427, 107 S.Ct. 484]; Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio (1986) 475 U.S. 574 [89 L.Ed.2d 538, 106 S.Ct. 1348]; A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc., supra, at pp. 1400 1402; Indiana Grocery, Inc. v. Super Valu Stores, Inc. (7th Cir. 1989) 864 F.2d 1409.) Even if business competitors engage in predatory pricing with the utmost malice directed at each other, the federal law is unconcerned unless predatory losses may be recouped and competition is thereby impaired. As the Supreme Court has observed concerning the federal law on predatory pricing, Absent some assurance that the hoped-for monopoly will materialize, and that it can be sustained for a significant period of time, [t]he predator must make a substantial investment with no assurance that it will pay off. [Citation.] For this reason, 11 For instance, section 13(a) of the Robinson-Patman Act forbids price discrimination where the effect of such discrimination may be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce . . . . (15 U.S.C. § 13(a), italics added.) there is a consensus among commentators that predatory pricing schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful. (Matsushita Elec., supra, at p. 589.) In section 17043, in contrast, the very gravamen of the offense is the purpose underlying the anticompetitive act, rather than the actual or threatened harm to competition. The intent or purpose of the below-cost sale is at the heart of the statute, and distinguishes the violation from a below-cost pricing strategy undertaken for legitimate, nonpredatory business reasons. (Food and G. Bureau of S. California v. United States (9th Cir. 1943) 139 F.2d 973, 974.) Section 17043 does not make all sales below average total cost illegal per se. Instead, such sales must have been made for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition. [Citations.] (William Inglis, etc. v. Itt Continental Baking Co. (9th Cir. 1981) 668 F.2d 1014, 1049; see also Food & G. Bureau, Inc., supra, at pp. 974 975.) The intent requirement imposed by section 17043 is an especially stringent one. Section 17043 uses the word purpose, not intent, not knowledge. (Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. Los Angeles Cellular Telephone Co., supra, 20 Cal.4th 163, 174.) Therefore, the California Supreme Court has concluded that to violate section 17043, a company must act with the purpose, i.e., the desire, of injuring competitors or destroying competition. (Id. at pp. 174 175; see also Chicago Title Ins. Co. v. Great Western Financial Corp. (1968) 69 Cal.2d 305, 323 [70 Cal.Rptr. 849, 444 P.2d 481]; Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court, supra, 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 330.) Further, section 17043 does not require an anticompetitive impact. [A]n injurious effect is not an essential element of the violation. The violation is complete when sales below cost are made with the requisite intent and not within any of the exceptions. (People v. Pay Less Drug Store (1944) 25 Cal.2d 108, 113 114 [153 P.2d 9].) The language of sections 17043 and 17071 make it sufficiently clear that the Legislature deemed that injury to a competitor or destruction of competition was an injurious effect, and therefore within the ban of the act; and that it was not necessary to await success in the monopolistic effort before the measures provided to safeguard the public interest and welfare could be invoked. (Pay Less Drug, supra, at p. 113.) While evidence of an injury due to a below-cost pricing scheme may establish the rebuttable statutory inference of unlawful purpose, the plaintiff may also prove purpose independently without any injurious effect. Even the objectives of the laws, though certainly similar, are not identical. The Sherman Act and Robinson-Patman Act (15 U.S.C. § 13(a)) seek to prevent anticompetitive acts that impair competition or harm competitors, whereas the UPA reflects a broader [l]egislative concern not only with the maintenance of competition, but with the maintenance of fair and honest competition. [Citations.] (ABC Internat. Traders, Inc. v. Matsushita Electric Corp. (1997) 14 Cal.4th 1247, 1262 [61 Cal.Rptr.2d 112, 931 P.2d 290].) We disagree with defendants characterization of the UPA as legislation that was merely intended to protect the public, not individual competitors. The UPA has been described by our high court as a legislative attempt to regulate business as a whole by prohibiting practices which the legislature has determined constitute unfair trade practices. (Wholesale T. Dealers v. National etc. Co. (1938) 11 Cal.2d 634, 643 [82 P.2d 3, 118 A.L.R. 486]; see also Max Factor & Co. v. Kunsman (1936) 5 Cal.2d 446, 478 [55 P.2d 177] (dis. opn. of Shenk, J.) [UPA appears to be a painstaking endeavor by the legislature to combat the abuses which the business interests have deemed unfair practices in the competitive field. ].) (Id. at p. 1256.) The history of the amalgamation of statutes that comprise the UPA teaches that a primary concern in the enactment of the UPA was the protection of smaller, independent retailers, especially grocers, against unfair competitive practices of the large chain stores. As a contemporary commentator explained, the prohibitions added in 1933 on secret rebates and unearned discounts (now section 17045) and below-cost sales (now section 17043) are designed to protect the retailer whose more powerful neighbor is attempting to drive him out of business. [Citations.] (ABC Internat., supra, at p. 1261; see also Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court, supra, 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 322.) The defendant s ability to recoup losses is unnecessary to the dual objectives of preventing unfair trade practices and protecting comparatively smaller enterprises from predatory pricing schemes of larger competitors. Thus, California and federal cases have recognized that the UPA in many respects does not mirror federal predatory pricing law. (William Inglis, etc. v. Itt Continental Baking Co., supra, 668 F.2d 1014, 1049; Kirk-Mayer, Inc. v. Pac Ord, Inc. (C.D.Cal. 1986) 626 F.Supp. 1168, 1173; Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court, supra, 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 325.)12 Defendant s reliance on federal law fails to acknowledge the significant differences between the language of the Sherman Act, the federal antitrust statute prohibiting predatory below-cost pricing, and its state counterpart, section 17043 of the UPA. (Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp., supra, at p. 325.) It has been observed that [t]he UPA, in contrast to the federal antitrust statutes, is precisely drawn to eliminate defined commercial practices such as predatory pricing. Therefore, changing judicial perspectives on antitrust enforcement have far less influence on the development of California predatory pricing law than on the development of the federal counterparts. (McCall, Private Enforcement of Predatory Price Laws Under the California Unlawful Practices Act and the Federal Antitrust Acts (1997) 28 Pacific L.J. 311, 315; . . .) (Id. at p. 326.) Additional features of the statutory construct of the UPA further persuade us that implication of recoupment ability as a requirement in section 17043 is neither necessary nor intended. Within other unfair trade provisions of the UPA that prohibit loss leaders (§§ 17030, 17044) and secret discriminatory rebates or allowances (§ 17045), the Legislature has seen fit in the language of the statutes to refer to potential injury to a competitor or the competitive structure, while statutes that prohibit locality price discrimination (§§ 17040 17042), like section 17043, are directed at the intent of the violation.13 The Legislature has thus evinced the ability in the UPA to target either the 12 In contrast, the federal anticompetition philosophies of the Sherman and Robinson-Patman Acts are often valuable in discussing the provisions of the California Cartwright Act (§ 16700 et seq.). (See SC Manufactured Homes, Inc. v. Liebert (2008) 162 Cal.App.4th 68, 90 [76 Cal.Rptr.39 73].) 13 For instance, section 17030 defines a loss leader as any article or product sold at less than cost: (a) Where the purpose is to induce, promote or encourage the purchase of other merchandise; or (b) Where the effect is a tendency or capacity to mislead or deceive purchasers purpose or ultimate effect of the violation, and clearly intended the former in the language of section 17043. We also point out that exceptions or defenses to the scope of the prohibition against below-cost sales, such as sales to meet competition, sales of damaged goods, or sales to close out stock, have been conspicuously delineated by the Legislature in section 17050; inability to recoup predatory losses is not among them. Finally, we are not convinced by defendants argument that the severe consequences of violation of section 17043 which may include fines, treble damages, and even potential criminal sanctions make the statute draconian without an implied recoupment requirement. The rigorous task imposed upon the plaintiff in a section 17043 action to prove that the below-cost sales were done for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition makes proof of a statutory violation formidable enough to justify the associated penalties. (Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court, supra, 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 330.) In light of the distinctions we discern, some glaring, some subtle, between section 17043 and the federal or other state predatory pricing laws,14 and particularly in light of the conspicuous focus of section 17043 upon the mental state of defendants purpose rather than ultimate impact of below-cost pricing, we decline to imply a recoupment or prospective purchasers; or (c) Where the effect is to divert trade from or otherwise injure competitors. (Italics added.) Section 17045 provides: The secret payment or allowance of rebates, refunds, commissions, or unearned discounts, whether in the form of money or otherwise, or secretly extending to certain purchasers special services or privileges not extended to all purchasers purchasing upon like terms and conditions, to the injury of a competitor and where such payment or allowance tends to destroy competition, is unlawful. (Italics added.) However, section 17040, more in line with section 17043, prohibits locality discrimination in the production, manufacture, distribution or sale of any article or product of general use or consumption, with intent to destroy the competition of any regular established dealer in such article or product, or to prevent the competition of any person who in good faith, intends and attempts to become such dealer, to create locality discriminations. (Italics added.) 14 We have reviewed the statutes and cases cited by defendant from other states, and find in them language and objectives that are distinguishable from section 17043. (See generally McCarthy, Whatever Happened to the Small Businessman? The California Unfair Practices Act (1968) 2 U.S.F. L.Rev. 165, 196 197; McCall, Private Enforcement of Predatory Price Laws Under the California Unlawful Practices Act and the Federal Antitrust Acts (1997) 28 Pac. L.J. 311, 338 339.) element in the statute where none has been expressed. We therefore conclude that the trial court, in its rulings on motions, the presentation of evidence, and instructions, did not err by refusing to recognize defendants recoupment claim.15 II. The Instructions on Purpose to Harm a Competitor. We turn to defendants challenge to the instructions and accompanying verdict form on the purpose requirement of section 17043. Defendants claim the instructions and verdict form erroneously permitted the jury to base liability on an intent to harm a single competitor, rather than the UPA term competitors. (Italics added.) Two instructions are at issue. In the first, the court explained the statutory presumption by stating that if the jury found any below-cost sales injured the Bay Guardian as a competitor, it is presumed that defendants purpose was to injure competitors and destroy competition. In the second, the court advised the jury that a defendant does not act with the required purpose under the statute merely because it had knowledge of probable substantial harm to a competitor or that customers would be diverted from a competitor. (Italics added.) The verdict form asked the jury to determine if defendants purpose was to injure a competitor or destroy competition. Defendants maintain that the effect of the instructions and verdict form was to direct the jury to impose liability merely by finding defendants made below-cost sales with a subjective intent to harm [the Guardian] alone, in contradistinction to the statutory language which prohibits belowcost pricing for the purpose of injuring competitors or [destroying] competition. (Italics added.) Defendants position is that the jury should have evaluated whether defendants purpose was to inflict market-wide injury. Defendants proposed interpretation of section 17043 is at odds with both common sense and the objectives of the statute. Defendants would have us interpret the law to 15 The instruction to the jury that specified what the plaintiff did not need to prove that it was economically rational for any defendant to act with the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition, or that a defendant would have had a reasonable expectation of recouping its losses by eliminating the plaintiff as a competitor may have been unnecessary, but we find that it was not prejudicial error. prohibit below-cost pricing only if multiple competitors are the target of an unlawful marketing scheme. As we have observed, the declared purposes of the UPA are to safeguard the public against the creation or perpetuation of monopolies and to foster and encourage competition, by prohibiting unfair, dishonest, deceptive, destructive, fraudulent and discriminatory practices by which fair and honest competition is destroyed or prevented. (§ 17001.) (ABC Internat. Traders, Inc. v. Matsushita Electric Corp., supra, 14 Cal.4th 1247, 1256.) The Legislature has also specifically directed that the UPA s provisions shall be liberally construed that its beneficial purposes may be subserved. (§ 17002.) (Ibid; see also Co-Opportunities v. National Broadcasting Co. (N.D.Cal. 1981) 510 F.Supp. 43, 49 50.) Thus, section 17043, like the remainder of the UPA, seeks to maintain fair and honest competition to protect smaller, independent retailers from the predatory practices of larger, more controlling competitors. (ABC, supra, at p. 1262.) The prohibitions against below-cost sales are designed to protect . . . [a competitor] whose more powerful neighbor is attempting to drive him out of business. [Citations.] (Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court, supra, 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 322, italics added, quoting from ABC Internat. Traders, Inc. v. Matsushita Electric Corp., supra, at p. 1261.) [I]njury to a competitor or destruction of competition is considered an injurious effect, and therefore within the ban of the UPA. (People v. Pay Less Drug Store, supra, 25 Cal.2d 108, 113, italics added.) In short, section 17043 is designed to reach a one-on-one clash between competitors, not just an effect on competition. A literal reading of section 17043 to require at least one economic actor in the field in addition to the defendant, so as to injure multiple competitors, would deprive the statute of much of its utility in at least two practical situations. If a given plaintiff and defendant are the only providers of an article or product, any head-to-head competition between them would be beyond the reach of section 17043 because neither is injuring competitors. Indeed, head-to-head competition was the legal focus of the section 17043 claim in Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise, supra. (The plaintiff was the Red & White Fleet, and defendant was Blue & Gold Fleet.) Moreover, defendants suggested interpretation of the law would immunize a business which serially engages in below-cost pricing to eliminate competitors one at a time, thereby permitting the very unlawful practices the statute seeks to proscribe. We are guided by maxims of statutory interpretation which direct us to avoid such illogical and meaningless consequences. (People v. Navarro (2007) 40 Cal.4th 668, 680 [54 Cal.Rptr.3d 766, 151 P.3d 1177].) If possible, the words should be interpreted to make them workable and reasonable [citations], . . . practical [citations], in accord with common sense and justice, and to avoid an absurd result [citations]. [Citation.] [Citation.] (Cummings v. Stanley (2009) 177 Cal.App.4th 493, 508 [99 Cal.Rptr.3d 284].) Giving the statute an interpretation that reaches only plural rather than singular competitors also conflicts with the more general directive of the Business and Professions Code that words used in the singular or plural refer to both. (§ 23008;16 see also People v. Manfredi (2008) 169 Cal.App.4th 622, 631 [86 Cal.Rptr.3d 810]; Cheek v. Superior Court (2002) 103 Cal.App.4th 520, 525 [126 Cal.Rptr.2d 820]; San Gabriel Valley Water Co. v. Hartford Accident & Indemnity Co. (2000) 82 Cal.App.4th 1230, 1240 [98 Cal.Rptr.2d 807].) We find that section 17043 applies to acts of below-cost pricing committed for the purpose of injuring either a single or multiple competitors or destroying competition. Therefore, the reference to a single competitor in the instructions and verdict form was not incorrect in the present case, particularly inasmuch as only a single competitor was the focus of the predatory pricing scheme. III. The Instructions on the Statutory Presumption. We move to defendants contention that the instructions on the statutory presumption of improper purpose (§ 17071) were defective. The court instructed the jury on the essential element of purpose by stating: It is only when a defendant sells advertising below cost and does so with the purpose, that is, desire of injuring 16 Section 23008 reads: Person includes any individual, firm, copartnership, joint adventure, association, corporation, estate, trust, business trust, receiver, syndicate, or any other group or combination acting as a unit, and the plural as well as the singular number. competitors or destroying competition, that such conduct is unlawful under California law. The court also advised the jury that, Purpose may be inferred from circumstantial evidence of a party s conduct or course of dealing, and may be proved the same way as any other fact may be proved either by direct or circumstantial evidence or by both direct and circumstantial evidence. In addition, pursuant to section 17071 the court gave the following instruction on the presumption of unlawful purpose: If you find that any defendant sold advertising space below cost, and any below-cost sales injured the Bay Guardian as a competitor, it is presumed that defendants purpose was to injure competitors and destroy competition. But this presumption may be overcome by other evidence. The court then proceeded to describe the nature of evidence that did not prove unlawful purpose. Defendants complain that the presumption instruction was incorrect for two reasons and thus should not have been given: first, once some rebuttal evidence was adduced that defendants did not act with an anticompetitive purpose, the presumption was rendered inoperative and the instruction became irrelevant; and second, the instruction improperly shifted plaintiff s burden to prove purpose to defendants to disprove it. In considering a claim of instructional error we must first ascertain what the relevant law provides, and then determine what meaning the instruction given conveys. (People v. Andrade (2000) 85 Cal.App.4th 579, 585 [102 Cal.Rptr.2d 254].) A court is required to instruct on the law applicable to the case, but no particular form is required; the instructions must be complete and a correct statement of the law. [Citation.] The meaning of instructions is tested by whether there is a reasonable likelihood that the jury misconstrued or misapplied the law in light of the instructions given, the entire record of trial, and the arguments of counsel. [Citation.] [T]he correctness of jury instructions is to be determined from the entire charge of the court, not from a consideration of parts of an instruction or from a particular instruction. [Citation.] [Citation.] Thus, absence of an essential element in a given instruction may be supplied by reference to another instruction, or cured in light of the instructions considered as a whole. (People v. Fiu (2008) 165 Cal.App.4th 360, 370 371 [81 Cal.Rptr.3d 32].) Dealing first with the claim that the presumption was no longer operative once defense presented evidence sufficient to support a finding of the nonexistence of the presumption, defendants do not dispute the presentation of adequate foundational evidence by plaintiff to trigger the initial presumption. Instead they claim that the presumption was effectively rebutted by their denial of anticompetitive purpose, which was sufficient evidence to take section 17071 s presumption out-of-play [sic]. The propriety of the presumption instruction in the present case depends upon whether the section 17071 presumption of purpose is viewed as one affecting the burden of proof or the burden of presenting evidence. The distinction has an important consequence when conflicting evidence is presented. A rebuttable presumption may affect the burden of proof or may affect the burden of producing evidence. (Evid. Code, § 601.) (In re Heather B. (1992) 9 Cal.App.4th 535, 560 [11 Cal.Rptr.2d 891].) A presumption affecting the burden of producing evidence requires the ultimate fact to be found from proof of the predicate facts in the absence of other evidence. If contrary evidence is introduced then the presumption has no further effect and the matter must be determined on the evidence presented. (Evid. Code, § 604.) (Id. at p. 561.) In contrast, a presumption affecting the burden of proof has a more substantial impact in determining the outcome of litigation. The effect of a presumption affecting the burden of proof is to impose upon the party against whom it operates the burden of proof as to the nonexistence of the presumed fact. (Evid. Code, § 606.) . . . [Citation.] (Gee v. Workers Comp. Appeals Bd. (2002) 96 Cal.App.4th 1418, 1425 [118 Cal.Rptr.2d 105]; see also Shadow Traffic Network v. Superior Court (1994) 24 Cal.App.4th 1067, 1085 [29 Cal.Rptr.2d 693].) [O]nce a presumption affecting the burden of proof comes into play, that is an issue which must be presented to the trier of fact. (Haycock v. Hughes Aircraft Co. (1994) 22 Cal.App.4th 1473, 1495 [28 Cal.Rptr.2d 248].) If contrary evidence is introduced, the jury has the right to weigh the evidence and determine whether it sufficiently contradicts the presumption. (Noble v. Key System, Ltd. (1935) 10 Cal.App.2d 132, 138 [51 P.2d 887].) A presumption affecting the burden of proof survives even though there is a conflict in the evidence, so in the face of conflicting evidence, the issue must be presented to the jury so long as there is some logical basis for the presumption. (Haycock, supra, at p. 1491.) We thus examine the nature and result of the presumption. Under section 17071, proof of one or more acts of selling or giving away any article or product below cost or at discriminatory prices, together with proof of the injurious effect of such acts, is presumptive evidence of the purpose or intent to injure competitors or destroy competition. (Fisherman s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court, supra, 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 321.) To create this presumption proof must be had, among other things, of one or more sales of an article or product below cost together with proof of the injurious effect of the practice. (Dooley s Hardware Mart v. Food Giant Markets, Inc. (1971) 21 Cal.App.3d 513, 517 [98 Cal.Rptr. 543].) Injurious effect is not explicitly defined in the statute, but has been interpreted to mean injury to a competitor or destruction of competition, consistent with the language of section 17043. (People v. Pay Less Drug Store, supra, 25 Cal.2d 108, 113.) The functionally identical presumption created by section 17071.517 of the UPA for loss leader sales has been found to be a presumption affecting the burden of proof, rather than the burden of producing evidence that is, if the presumption arises defendants are required to prove they did not intend to injure competitors or destroy competition through their use of predatory pricing. (Dooley s Hardware Mart v. Food Giant Markets, Inc., supra, 21 Cal.App.3d 513, 517 518, italics added.) Like section 17071.5, we conclude that the section 17071 presumption is properly categorized as one that affects the burden of proof rather than merely the burden of 17 Section 17071.5 reads: In all actions brought under this chapter proof of limitation of the quantity of any article or product sold or offered for sale to any one customer to a quantity less than the entire supply thereof owned or possessed by the seller or which he is otherwise authorized to sell at the place of such sale or offering for sale, together with proof that the price at which the article or product is so sold or offered for sale is in fact below its invoice or replacement cost, whichever is lower, raises a presumption of the purpose or intent to injure competitors or destroy competition. This section applies only to sales by persons conducting a retail business the principal part of which involves the resale to consumers of commodities purchased or acquired for that purpose, as distinguished from persons principally engaged in the sale to consumers of commodities of their own production or manufacture. persuasion. (See Dooley s Hardware Mart v. Food Giant Markets, Inc., supra, 21 Cal.App.3d 513, 517 518.) A presumption affecting the burden of proof shifts the burden of persuasion on an ultimate fact to the party against whom the presumption operates upon a finding of the predicate facts. (Evid. Code, § 606.) (In re Heather B., supra, 9 Cal.App.4th 535, 560.) A presumption meant to establish or implement some public policy other than facilitation of the particular action in which it applies is a presumption affecting the burden of proof. (People v. Dubon (2001) 90 Cal.App.4th 944, 953 [108 Cal.Rptr.2d 914]; see also Evid. Code, § 605; Reeves v. Workers Comp. Appeals Bd. (2000) 80 Cal.App.4th 22, 30 [95 Cal.Rptr.2d 74].) As we view section 17071, the presumption is indicative of an effort by the Legislature to implement the public policy of facilitating proof of unlawful purpose of below-cost sales which injure a competitor by shifting the burden of proof to the party more in possession of relevant evidence demonstrating the true intent associated with the pricing scheme. (People v. Pay Less Drug Store, supra, 25 Cal.2d 108, 114 115.) Thus, the presumption is intended to affect the burden of proof. (Gee v. Workers Comp. Appeals Bd., supra, 96 Cal.App.4th 1418, 1426.) Further, the stated consequence of the articulated presumption demonstrates that it modifies the burden of proof. [T]he obvious and only effect of the presumption created by section 17071 is to require the defendant to go forward with proof to negate the presumption of wrongful intent. (Western Union Financial Services, Inc. v. First Data Corp. (1993) 20 Cal.App.4th 1530, 1540 [25 Cal.Rptr.2d 341], italics added.) [T]he allocation of evidentiary burdens [under section 17071 is] as follows: Assuming proof of injury to a competitor has been made, California law allows plaintiffs to establish a prima facie case with proof of prices below average total cost. The defendant then has the burden of negating the inference of illegal intent or establishing an affirmative defense. [Citation.] (Turnbull & Turnbull v. ARA Transportation, Inc., supra, 219 Cal.App.3d 811, 824 825.) The presumption may be rebutted by establishing one of the statute s affirmative defenses, such as meeting competition, see Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17050, or by showing that the sales were made in good faith and not for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition. [Citation.] (William Inglis, etc. v. Itt Continental Baking Co., supra, 668 F.2d 1014, 1049; see also Dooley s Hardware Mart v. Food Giant Markets, Inc., supra, 21 Cal.App.3d 513, 518.) After proof of the sales below cost and injury resulting therefrom, there is no undue hardship cast upon the defendants to require them to come forward with evidence of their true intent as against the prima facie showing, or with evidence which will bring them within a specified exception in the act. (People v. Pay Less Drug Store, supra, 25 Cal.2d 108, 115.) Once the presumption is rebutted, the burden shifts back to the moving party to offer actual proof of injurious intent. (Western Union Financial Services, Inc. v. First Data Corp., supra, at p. 1540.) The section 17071 presumption, being one that in both nature and consequence alters the burden of proof, did not disappear in the face of evidence as to the nonexistence of the presumed fact. . . . [Citations.] (Haycock v. Hughes Aircraft Co., supra, 22 Cal.App.4th 1473, 1495.) Therefore, the fact that defendants denied any purpose to harm competition, and produced some evidence of good faith efforts to compete in the marketplace, did not negate plaintiff s right to an instruction on a presumption affecting the burden of proof of unlawful purpose. Defendants may have offered rebuttal evidence, but they did not negate the presumption by conclusive proof that negated unlawful purpose as a matter of law or compelled a finding on the issue in their favor based on this record. (See Xebec Development Partners, Ltd. v. National Union Fire Ins. Co. (1993) 12 Cal.App.4th 501, 552 [15 Cal.Rptr.2d 726], reversed on other grounds Essex Ins. Co. v. Five Star Dye House, Inc. (2006) 38 Cal.4th 1252, 1265 [45 Cal.Rptr.3d 362, 137 P.3d 192].) Despite the defense efforts to rebut the section 17071 presumption, at least substantial evidence in support of the presumption instruction remained. A party is entitled upon request to correct, nonargumentative instructions on every theory of the case advanced by him which is supported by substantial evidence. (Soule v. General Motors Corp. (1994) 8 Cal.4th 548, 572 [34 Cal.Rptr.2d 607, 882 P.2d 298]; see also Munoz v. City of Union City (2004) 120 Cal.App.4th 1077, 1107 1108 [16 Cal.Rptr.3d 521].) Substantial evidence necessary to support a jury instruction is evidence sufficient to deserve consideration by the jury, i.e., evidence from which a jury composed of reasonable [persons] could have concluded that the particular facts underlying the instruction did exist. . . . [Citation.] (People v. Strozier (1993) 20 Cal.App.4th 55, 63 [24 Cal.Rptr.2d 362]; see also People v. Marshall (1997) 15 Cal.4th 1, 39 40 [61 Cal.Rptr.2d 84, 931 P.2d 262]; National Medical Transportation Network v. Deloitte & Touche (1998) 62 Cal.App.4th 412, 429 [72 Cal.Rptr.2d 720].) Evidence is substantial if a reasonable jury could find it persuasive [citation] and therefore conclude that the particular facts underlying the instruction did exist [citation]. (People v. Elam (2001) 91 Cal.App.4th 298, 308 [110 Cal.Rptr.2d 185].) Substantial evidence to support the presumption was presented, and the contradictory rebuttal evidence offered by defendants did not irrefutably disprove purpose. Plaintiff was therefore entitled to the benefit of an instruction on the section 17071 presumption, just as defendants were entitled to an instruction that the presumption was subject to rebuttal. (Lara v. Nevitt (2004) 123 Cal.App.4th 454, 460 [19 Cal.Rptr.3d 865]; Haycock v. Hughes Aircraft Co., supra, 22 Cal.App.4th 1473, 1492, 1495.) Turning to the second prong of defendants challenge to the presumption instruction, we find nothing in the instruction that erroneously shifted the burden of proof. The trial court gave a definitive standard instruction that plaintiff bore the burden to prove by a preponderance of the evidence all of the elements of the case, and specifically that the defendant s purpose was to injure competitors or destroy competition. Thus, the jury knew that plaintiff retained the essential burden to prove the unlawful purpose of the sales. The court then advised the jury that unlawful purpose may be proved the same way as any other fact, by direct or circumstantial evidence. The presumption was explained with an instruction that if the jury found below-cost sales injured the Bay Guardian as a competitor, it is presumed that defendants purpose was to injure competitors and destroy competition. The rebuttal part of the instruction stated, But this presumption may be overcome by other evidence. The section 17071 instruction thus merely stated a rebuttable permissive presumption or inference which allowed, but did not compel, the trier of fact to infer the elemental fact from proof by plaintiff of other foundational facts. (See People v. Parson (2008) 44 Cal.4th 332, 355 356 [79 Cal.Rptr.3d 269, 187 P.3d 1]; People v. McCall (2004) 32 Cal.4th 175, 182 183 [8 Cal.Rptr.3d 337, 82 P.3d 351].) The instruction did not create a mandatory presumption that operated to shift plaintiff s burden of proof to the defense, as the jury was not required to draw the described inference. (People v. Parson, supra, at p. 356; People v. McCall, supra, at p. 183, fn. 5; People v. Yeoman (2003) 31 Cal.4th 93, 131 [2 Cal.Rptr.3d 186, 72 P.3d 1166].) Further, nothing in the instruction directly or indirectly relieved plaintiff of its burden to establish proof of unlawful purpose. (People v. Prieto (2003) 30 Cal.4th 226, 248 [133 Cal.Rptr.2d 18, 66 P.3d 1123].) The most common evidentiary device is the entirely permissive inference or presumption, which leaves the trier of fact free to credit or reject the inference and does not shift the burden of proof to the defense. (Ulster County Court v. Allen (1979) 442 U.S. 140, 157 [60 L.Ed.2d 777, 99 S.Ct. 2213].) In any event, given the court s other instructions regarding the burden of proof and proper consideration and weighing of evidence, the presumption instruction did not shift or reduce plaintiff s burden of proof in this case. (People v. Parson, supra, at p. 356; Cristler v. Express Messenger Systems, Inc. (2009) 171 Cal.App.4th 72, 84 [89 Cal.Rptr.3d 34]; Sargent Fletcher, Inc. v. Able Corp. (2003) 110 Cal.App.4th 1658, 1673 1674 [3 Cal.Rptr.3d 279]; People v. Gonzalez (1995) 33 Cal.App.4th 1440, 1443 [39 Cal.Rptr.2d 778]; People v. Carter (1993) 19 Cal.App.4th 1236, 1252 1253 [23 Cal.Rptr.2d 888].) Furthermore, our duty is to look at the instructions as a whole, not in isolation, and we must assume jurors are able to correlate, follow, and understand the court s instructions. (People v. Vang (2009) 171 Cal.App.4th 1120, 1129 [90 Cal.Rptr.3d 328]; People v. Ibarra (2007) 156 Cal.App.4th 1174, 1192 1193 [67 Cal.Rptr.3d 871].) We conclude that no shift in the burden of proof occurred with the presumption instruction, as the jury was aware from the totality of the instructions that a verdict could not be rendered in favor of plaintiff unless a finding was made based on a preponderance of the evidence that defendants did in fact make belowcost sales with the requisite purpose. The minor flaw we perceive in the instruction, when it is viewed in isolation, is that it was somewhat incomplete. In addition to the admonition that the presumption may be overcome by other evidence, the instruction should have more specifically advised the jury that the presumption was rebutted with proof by defendants of the nonexistence of the presumed fact of unlawful purpose by a preponderance of the evidence. (See Shadow Traffic Network v. Superior Court, supra, 24 Cal.App.4th 1067, 1085; Haycock v. Hughes Aircraft Co., supra, 22 Cal.App.4th 1473, 1495.) When we again view the instructions in their entirety, however, we find no prejudicial error. The additional instructions thoroughly defined for the jury the evidence that negated proof of purpose. IV. The Evidence of Damages. Defendants also argue that plaintiff failed to adequately prove the element of damages caused by the below-cost sales. They posit that proof of damages under the UPA must link particular lost customers to particular below-cost sales. Defendants claim that none of the models of damages or testimony offered by plaintiff s expert Kupperberg linked even one lost customer to below-cost sales. In light of the lack of connection between sales and lost profits, defendants maintain that there was a complete failure of proof on both causation and damages, which requires that we reverse with directions to enter judgment in their favor. [A] plaintiff pursuing the remedies under the Unfair Practices Act is entitled to recover the amount of the actual damages sustained by him, in addition to injunctive relief. (Sandler v. Gordon (1949) 94 Cal.App.2d 254, 258 [210 P.2d 314].)18 The UPA does not further define the damages recoverable by a plaintiff, or specify any measure of compensatory damages, other than to state, in pertinent part, in section 17082: In any 18 Section 17070 provides: Any person or trade association may bring an action to enjoin and restrain any violation of this chapter and, in addition thereto, for the recovery of damages. action under this chapter, it is not necessary to allege or prove actual damages or the threat thereof, or actual injury or the threat thereof, to the plaintiff. But, in addition to injunctive relief, any plaintiff in any such action shall be entitled to recover three times the amount of the actual damages, if any, sustained by the plaintiff, as well as three times the actual damages, if any, sustained by any person who has assigned to the plaintiff his claim for damages resulting from a violation of this chapter. Defendants essential premise that proof of damages must relate particular belowcost sales to loss of particular customers or profits is not articulated in the UPA, nor is it consistent with established standards for damage awards in cases of injury to business. The measure of damages caused by acts of unfair competition is the actual damage suffered by virtue of profits on sales actually diverted from plaintiff s business. [Citation.] (Klamath-Orleans Lumber, Inc. v. Miller (1978) 87 Cal.App.3d 458, 466 [151 Cal.Rptr. 118].) Damage awards in injury to business cases are based on net profits. [Citation.] Net profits are the gains made from sales after deducting the value of the labor, materials, rents, and all expenses, together with the interest of the capital employed. [Citation.] [Citations.] [Citation.] Lost anticipated profits cannot be recovered if it is uncertain whether any profit would have been derived at all from the proposed undertaking. But lost prospective net profits may be recovered if the evidence shows, with reasonable certainty, both their occurrence and extent. [Citation] It is enough to demonstrate a reasonable probability that profits would have been earned except for the defendant s conduct. [Citations.] . . . [Citation.] (Electronic Funds Solutions, LLC v. Murphy (2005) 134 Cal.App.4th 1161, 1180 [36 Cal.Rptr.3d 663], italics added.) It is also a general proposition in assessing damages in this context that there is a distinction between sufficient proof of the fact of damage, and adequate proof of the amount of damage. Where the fact of damages is certain, the amount of damages need not be calculated with absolute certainty. [Citations.] The law requires only that some reasonable basis of computation of damages be used, and the damages may be computed even if the result reached is an approximation. [Citation.] This is especially true where, as here, it is the wrongful acts of the defendant that have created the difficulty in proving the amount of loss of profits [citations] or where it is the wrongful acts of the defendant that have caused the other party to not realize a profit to which that party is entitled. [Citations.] [¶] . . . [¶] The selection of which measure of damages to apply is within the sound discretion of the trier of fact. (GHK Associates v. Mayer Group, Inc. (1990) 224 Cal.App.3d 856, 873 874 [274 Cal.Rptr. 168], emphasis in original.) Where, as here, injury has occurred to an established business, lost profits may be recovered if their extent and occurrence can be ascertained with reasonable certainty; once their existence has been so established, recovery will not be denied because the amount cannot be shown with mathematical precision. [Citations.] [Citation.] (Resort Video, Ltd. v. Laser Video, Inc. (1995) 35 Cal.App.4th 1679, 1697 1698 [42 Cal.Rptr.2d 136].) Where an established business s operation is prevented or interrupted, damages for the loss of prospective profits that otherwise might have been made from its operation are generally recoverable for the reason that their occurrence and extent may be ascertained with reasonable certainty from the past volume of business and other provable data relevant to the probable future sales. [Citations.] [Citations.] (Parlour Enterprises, Inc. v. Kirin Group, Inc. (2007) 152 Cal.App.4th 281, 287 288 [61 Cal.Rptr.3d 243].) Exact or precise calculations are not required; fair approximations based on personal knowledge will suffice: [T]he general rule [is] that while a plaintiff must show with reasonable certainty that he has suffered damages by reason of the wrongful act of defendant, once the cause and existence of damages have been so established, recovery will not be denied because the damages are difficult of ascertainment. [Citations.] (Mardirossian & Associates, Inc. v. Ersoff (2007) 153 Cal.App.4th 257, 269 [62 Cal.Rptr.3d 665].) Because plaintiffs successfully established that the failure to realize profits was the result of defendants purposeful behavior, the defendants cannot complain if the probable profits are of necessity estimated. (Natural Soda Prod. Co. v. City of L.A. (1943) 23 Cal.2d 193, 200 [143 P.2d 12].) [A]n injured person [may] not be deprived of substantial compensation merely because he cannot prove with complete certainty the extent of harm he has suffered. Particularly is this true in situations . . . where the harm is of such a nature as necessarily to prevent anything approximating accuracy of proof, as when anticipated profits of a business have been prevented. (Rest.2d Torts, § 912, com. a, p. 479, emphasis added.) Thus, plaintiff was required to prove that actual damages occurred by virtue of profits on sales actually diverted from the Guardian, but was not also required to prove the precise amounts of damages attributable to the loss of individual customers or sales due to defendants predatory pricing. A plaintiff must show loss of net pecuniary gain, not loss of a particular customer or source of revenue. (Parlour Enterprises, Inc. v. Kirin Group, Inc., supra, 152 Cal.App.4th 281, 287, italics added, quoting Kids Universe v. In2Labs (2002) 95 Cal.App.4th 870, 884 [116 Cal.Rptr.2d 158].) The extent of such damages may be measured by the past volume of business and other provable data relevant to the probable future sales. [Citation.] (Shade Foods, Inc. v. Innovative Products Sales & Marketing, Inc. (2000) 78 Cal.App.4th 847, 890 [93 Cal.Rptr.2d 364]; see also Stott v. Johnston (1951) 36 Cal.2d 864, 875 [229 P.2d 348].) Also, California courts have permitted the experience of similar businesses to be one way to prove prospective profits. (Kids Universe v. In2Labs, supra, 95 Cal.App.4th 870, 885; Berge v. International Harvester Co. (1983) 142 Cal.App.3d 152, 163 [190 Cal.Rptr. 815].) The comparables considered by Kupperberg as well as Johnson, and the continued profitability of the Palo Alto Weekly and the Pacific Sun, provide appropriate and convincing evidence of prospective profits. It is acknowledged that expert testimony alone is a sufficient basis for proof of lost profits if that opinion is supported by tangible evidence with sufficient factual basis. (Kids Universe, supra, at p. 885.) The damages models explained by Kupperberg took into account the past volume of the Guardian s business and the probable effect of the below-cost sales upon revenues and net profits. (See Sandler v. Gordon, supra, 94 Cal.App.2d 254, 258 259.) We conclude that the failure of plaintiff to correlate lost profits with individual transactions does not defeat its claim for damages. Moving to our review of the jury s determination of the amount of compensation awarded plaintiff, we are subject to narrow constraints. First, the contention that the evidence does not support the verdict is reviewed under the substantial evidence standard. In reviewing a claim of insufficiency of evidence, the appellate court must consider the whole record, view the evidence in the light most favorable to the judgment, presume every fact the trier of fact could reasonably deduce from the evidence, and defer to the trier of fact s determination of the weight and credibility of the evidence. (Rufo v. Simpson (2001) 86 Cal.App.4th 573, 614 [103 Cal.Rptr.2d 492].) [T]he power of the appellate court begins and ends with a determination as to whether there is any substantial evidence, contradicted or uncontradicted, which will support the conclusion reached by the jury. [Citation.] (Shade Foods, Inc. v. Innovative Products Sales & Marketing, Inc., supra, 78 Cal.App.4th 847, 889.) At bottom, the determination of damages is essentially a factual matter on which inevitable differences of opinion do not warrant intervention by the appellate courts. (Heiner v. Kmart Corp. (2000) 84 Cal.App.4th 335, 347 [100 Cal.Rptr.2d 854].) We find in the record convincing evidence of the fact of damages suffered by plaintiff as a result of the SF Weekly s predatory pricing scheme. The Guardian s controller examined numerous customer ledgers for advertising transactions during the damages period and discovered that defendants below-cost pricing caused either a total loss of customers or a loss of revenue in over 65 percent of those transactions. Although the Guardian cut its advertising costs during the damages period, advertising rates were reduced to compete with defendants pricing scheme, and revenue dropped by 50 percent between 2000 and 2007. The testimony of plaintiff s expert Clifford Kupperberg provided a competent, logical foundation for projecting the amount of lost net profits over the damages period, and cannot be discounted merely because individual sales were not calculated and the total amount was not established with mathematical precision. (See Heiner v. Kmart Corp., supra, 84 Cal.App.4th 335, 347; Shade Foods, Inc. v. Innovative Products Sales & Marketing, Inc., supra, 78 Cal.App.4th 847, 889 890; Berge v. International Harvester Co., supra, 142 Cal.App.3d 152, 161.) As Kupperberg testified, associating losses with particular sales was neither functional nor feasible in a case such as this one which encompassed many years and a vast number of transactions. Kupperberg s models may have left room for evaluation by the jury, but his testimony furnished the jury with at least the requisite reasonable basis for a fair approximation of damages, even if the result reached lacked precision. (See Mardirossian & Associates, Inc. v. Ersoff, supra, 153 Cal.App.4th 257, 269; Shade Foods, supra, at p. 890.)19 We recognize that Kupperberg s testimony was adeptly challenged by defendants. Their expert Everett Harry asserted that Kupperberg s models failed to account for other factors that contributed to loss of revenue, and were both speculative and exaggerated. Defendants attack on Kupperberg s testimony, however, is essentially a request for this court reweigh the expert testimony, draw inferences not drawn by the jury, and substitute our judgment for that of the trier of fact, which we cannot do. (Heiner v. Kmart Corp., supra, 84 Cal.App.4th 335, 347; People v. Miller (1994) 25 Cal.App.4th 913, 919 [31 Cal.Rptr.2d 423].) Technical arguments about the meaning and effect of expert testimony on the issue of damages are best directed to the jury. (Heiner v. Kmart Corp., supra, at p. 347.) Defendants also presented evidence of various economic considerations that reduced advertising revenue and net profits for weekly alternative newspapers: competition from the internet, direct mailing, and other sources, in addition to the general downturn in business. The defense evidence was credible, but not definitive, and plaintiff offered contrary persuasive evidence of the continued profitability of weekly newspapers in the area, such as the Palo Alto Weekly and the Pacific Sun, despite the economic recession and competition for advertising revenue. We cannot reweigh the conflicting evidence, and are justified in interfering with the jury s determination only when the award is so disproportionate to the injuries suffered that it shocks the conscience and 19 We agree with defendants that Kupperberg s minimum change model, which assumed no lost revenue to the Guardian due to increased competition from the SF Weekly, is flawed under the facts presented. Even without below-cost pricing, it seems likely that the SF Weekly, given a massive influx of funding and support from the New Times, would have made inroads into the Guardian s market share of advertising revenue. virtually compels the conclusion the award is attributable to passion or prejudice. (Rufo v. Simpson, supra, 86 Cal.App.4th 573, 615.) The damages awarded by the jury for plaintiff s lost profits in the present case do not reach that extreme disproportionate level. We therefore will not disturb the award, which is also supported by substantial evidence. (Heiner v. Kmart Corp., supra, 84 Cal.App.4th 335, 347; Wanland v. Los Gatos Lodge, Inc. (1991) 230 Cal.App.3d 1507, 1518 1519 [281 Cal.Rptr. 890]; Rodriguez v. McDonnell Douglas Corp. (1978) 87 Cal.App.3d 626, 656 [151 Cal.Rptr. 399].) V. The Judgment against the New Times and the East Bay Weekly. We reach defendants final contention, which is that the judgment against the New Times and the Express as agents of the SF Weekly cannot stand. The liability of agents for acts that violate the UPA is delineated in section 17095 rather awkwardly as follows: Any person, who, either as director, officer or agent of any firm or corporation or as agent of any person, violating the provisions of this chapter, assists or aids, directly or indirectly, in such violation is responsible therefor equally with the person, firm or corporation for which he acts. Defendants claim that the damages award against the New Times and the Express as agents is unjustified unless the evidence proved they acted as the SF Weekly s agent in 100% of the sales for which the jury awarded liability. They also argue that since there was no substantial evidence to support any finding of agency, the jury verdict cannot stand and the trial court erred by denying the JNOV for these two entities. Defendants ask us to reverse the judgment against the New Times and the Express, and direct entry of judgment in their favor. An agent is not defined in section 17095 or elsewhere in the UPA. Therefore, it is appropriate to consider general principles of agency law. An agent is one who represents a principal in dealings with third persons. (Civ. Code, § 2295.) An agent is a person authorized by the principal to conduct one or more transactions with one or more third persons and to exercise a degree of discretion in effecting the purpose of the principal. (Fiol v. Doellstedt (1996) 50 Cal.App.4th 1318, 1328 [58 Cal.Rptr.2d 308].)20 The essential characteristics of an agency relationship as laid out in the Restatement are as follows: (1) An agent or apparent agent holds a power to alter the legal relations between the principal and third persons and between the principal and himself; (2) an agent is a fiduciary with respect to matters within the scope of the agency; and (3) a principal has the right to control the conduct of the agent with respect to matters entrusted to him. [Citation.] [Citations.] [Citation.] (Garlock Sealing Technologies, LLC v. NAK Sealing Technologies Corp. (2007) 148 Cal.App.4th 937, 964 [56 Cal.Rptr.3d 177].) An agency is proved by evidence that the [entity] for whom the work was performed had the right to control the activities of the alleged agent. [Citation.] Thus, the hallmark of agency is the exercise of control over the agent by the principal. (F. Hoffman-La Roche, Ltd. v. Superior Court (2005) 130 Cal.App.4th 782, 797 [30 Cal.Rptr.3d 407]; see also Michelson v. Hamada (1994) 29 Cal.App.4th 1566, 1579 [36 Cal.Rptr.2d 343].) In the absence of the essential characteristic of the right of control, there is no true agency . . . . [Citations.] (van t Rood v. County of Santa Clara (2003) 113 Cal.App.4th 549, 572 [6 Cal.Rptr.3d 746].) An agency may arise by express agreement or may be implied from the conduct of the parties. [Citation.] [Citation.] (van t Rood v. County of Santa Clara, supra, 113 Cal.App.4th 549, 571; see also Michelson v. Hamada, supra, 29 Cal.App.4th 1566, 1579.) However, an agency cannot be created by the conduct of the agent alone; rather, conduct by the principal is essential to create the agency. Agency can be established either by agreement between the agent and the principal, that is, a true agency [citation], or it can be founded on ostensible authority, that is, some intentional conduct or neglect on the part of the alleged principal creating a belief in the minds of third persons that an agency exists, and a reasonable reliance thereon by such third persons. 20 Civil Code section 2295 states: An agent is one who represents another, called the principal, in dealings with third persons. Such representation is called agency. [Citations.] The principal must in some manner indicate that the agent is to act for him, and the agent must act or agree to act on his behalf and subject to his control. . . . [Citations.] . . . [Citation.] (Flores v. Evergreen at San Diego, LLC (2007) 148 Cal.App.4th 581, 587 588 [55 Cal.Rptr.3d 823], italics omitted.) The existence of an agency relationship is a factual question for the trier of fact, whose determination must be affirmed on appeal if supported by substantial evidence. (Garlock Sealing Technologies, LLC v. NAK Sealing Technologies Corp., supra, 148 Cal.App.4th 937, 965; see also Violette v. Shoup (1993) 16 Cal.App.4th 611, 619 [20 Cal.Rptr.2d 358].) If such substantial evidence be found, it is of no consequence that the trial court believing other evidence, or drawing other reasonable inferences, might have reached a contrary conclusion. [Citation.] (Jameson v. Five Feet Restaurant, Inc. (2003) 107 Cal.App.4th 138, 143 [131 Cal.Rptr.2d 771], italics omitted.) The record before us contains substantial evidence to support the jury verdict that imposed liability on the New Times as the SF Weekly s agent. Under the facts presented here, we find that the New Times may incur liability as an agent under section 17095 for the entirety of the predatory pricing scheme without evidence of participation in every transaction that violated section 17043. We have before us the case of an ongoing, comprehensive below-cost pricing scheme instigated and executed conjointly by two parties. Liability is appropriately attached to the entirety of damages suffered by plaintiff as a result of the scheme, not just to individual transactions. We therefore conclude that agency status must be assessed from the perspective of the overall arrangement rather than by reference to individual transactions. When the below-cost pricing violations are so viewed in their totality, we are persuaded that the New Times assisted and aided in the violations as an agent of the SF Weekly. Evidence was presented that the New Times, through its executive editor, essentially implemented the pricing scheme after the acquisition of the SF Weekly, and agreed to fund the anticipated losses necessary to engage in an advertising rate battle to obtain customers from the Guardian. Sales representatives of the SF Weekly were authorized by the New Times to offer advertising at rates lower than cost, and advised that expected losses would be covered by the New Times, even for a period of many years. The chief operating officer of the New Times personally negotiated a below-cost advertising transaction with Bill Graham Productions on behalf of the SF Weekly that siphoned a massive advertising account from the Guardian. Other large advertising accounts which offered below-cost rates were managed for the SF Weekly by employees of the New Times. Inter-company e-mails, memoranda and letters reveal that principals and other high ranking officers of the New Times actively participated in and ratified the program to offer below-cost rates to gain advertising revenue at the expense of the Guardian. At the same time, the SF Weekly retained discretion to control the specific prices offered for display advertising in the paper. The evidence, while in conflict, demonstrates that the requisite agency relationship existed with the approval of both parties, and that both acted in concert to promote and implement the below-cost pricing scheme that violated section 17043. The same cannot be said of the Express. First, the Express was not acquired by the New Times until well after below-cost pricing scheme was initiated. The Express may have participated, through its affiliation with the New Times as its parent company, in transactions that offered below-cost rates for display advertising in conjunction with the SF Weekly. However, nothing in the record indicates to us that the Express either held power to alter the legal relations between the principal and third parties, or that the SF Weekly as principal had the right to control the conduct of the Express with respect to matters related to the pricing scheme. As we view the evidence, the Express was acting under the control of the New Times, not the SF Weekly. More importantly, the evidence fails to suggest that the Express in any way voluntarily consented to an arrangement to act as agent for the SF Weekly to assist with perpetration of below-cost pricing violations. (Pagarigan v. Libby Care Center, Inc. (2002) 99 Cal.App.4th 298, 301 302 [120 Cal.Rptr.2d 892].) [T]he formation of an agency relationship is a bilateral matter. Words or conduct by both principal and agent are necessary to create the relationship . . . . [Citation.] (Flores v. Evergreen at San Diego, LLC, supra, 148 Cal.App.4th 581, 588; see also Hanks v. Carter & Higgins of Cal., Inc. (1967) 250 Cal.App.2d 156, 163 [58 Cal.Rptr. 190].) We conclude that the judgment against the Express is not based on substantial evidence of an agency relationship with the SF Weekly. (Flores v. Evergreen, supra, at pp. 587 588.) DISPOSITION Accordingly, the judgment against defendant East Bay Express is reversed. In all other respects the judgment is affirmed. __________________________________ Dondero, J. We concur: __________________________________ Marchiano, P. J. __________________________________ Margulies, J. Trial Court San Francisco County Superior Court Trial Judge Honorable Marla Miller For Defendants and Appellants Reed Smith LLP Paul D. Fogel, Esq. Raymond A. Cardozo, Esq. Dennis Peter Maio, Esq.; Kerr & Wagstaffe LLP H. Sinclair Kerr, Jr., Esq. James M. Wagstaffe, Esq. Ivo Labar, Esq.; Village Voice Media, LLC Don Bennett Moon, Esq. For Plaintiff and Respondent Joseph A. Hearst, Esq.; E. Craig Moody, Esq.; Ralph C. Alldredge, Esq.; Richard P. Hill, Esq.

Some case metadata and case summaries were written with the help of AI, which can produce inaccuracies. You should read the full case before relying on it for legal research purposes.

This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.