In re Google Play Consumer Antitrust Litigation, No. 3:2020cv05761 - Document 448 (N.D. Cal. 2023)

Court Description: ORDER RE MERITS OPINIONS OF DR. HAL J. SINGER. Signed by Judge James Donato on 8/28/2023. (jdlc2, COURT STAFF) (Filed on 8/28/2023)

Download PDF
In re Google Play Consumer Antitrust Litigation Doc. 448 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 1 of 19 1 2 3 4 5 6 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT 7 NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA 8 9 IN RE GOOGLE PLAY STORE ANTITRUST LITIGATION Member Case Nos. 20-cv-05761-JD, 21-cv-05227-JD 10 11 United States District Court Northern District of California MDL Case No. 21-md-02981-JD ORDER RE MERITS OPINIONS OF DR. HAL J. SINGER 12 13 14 15 In this multidistrict antitrust litigation, several plaintiff groups have challenged Google’s 16 Play Store practices. The Play Store is a marketplace that offers millions of apps for devices that 17 use the Android operating system, such as phones and tablets made by Samsung and other original 18 equipment manufacturers. The apps in the Play Store are created and supplied by independent 19 developers, many of whom charge users a fee to acquire the app or in-app content. A central 20 theme in all of the constituent cases of the MDL action is that Google illegally monopolized the 21 Android app distribution market in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, which is 22 said to have caused overcharges to consumers and other injuries. 23 This order pertains primarily to the consumers case, In re Google Play Consumer Antitrust 24 Litigation, Case No. 20-cv-05761-JD. The consumers sued Google, LLC, Google Ireland 25 Limited, Google Commerce Limited, Google Asia Pacific Pte. Limited, and Google Payment 26 Corp. as defendants. In keeping with the parties’ practice in the MDL, defendants are referred to 27 collectively as “Google.” 28 Dockets.Justia.com Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 2 of 19 The consumer plaintiffs have proffered the opinions of Dr. Hal J. Singer, an economist at United States District Court Northern District of California 1 2 the consulting firm, Econ One, and the University of Utah, as an essential part of their case against 3 Google. Dr. Singer previously provided opinion testimony in support of the consumers’ motion to 4 certify a class. After a concurrent expert evidentiary proceeding (known informally as a “hot tub”) 5 in which Dr. Singer exchanged views on key topics with Google’s expert, Dr. Michelle Burtis, an 6 economist at Charles River Associates, the Court denied Google’s motion to exclude Dr. Singer’s 7 opinions, and certified a consumer class. See Dkt. Nos. 302 (Class Cert. Hot Tub Tr.), 383 (Class 8 Cert. Order).1 An appeal of the grant of certification is pending before the circuit court. See In re 9 Google Play Store Antitrust Litigation, Case No. 23-15285 (9th Cir.). 10 The consumer plaintiffs have also asked Dr. Singer to provide opinion testimony at trial on 11 the merits of their antitrust claims against Google. The Court has denied Google’s request to defer 12 or stay the November 6, 2023, jury trial, see Dkt. No. 499, and so proceedings have moved 13 forward to the consideration of motions by Google for partial summary judgment and to exclude 14 the merits opinions of certain experts on the plaintiffs’ side. See Dkt. Nos. 483, 484, 487.2 For the 15 experts, Google has asked to exclude under Rule 702 of the Federal Rules of Evidence (FRE) the 16 merits opinions of Dr. Singer, and of Dr. Marc Rysman, an economist at Boston University 17 retained by the State plaintiffs. See Dkt. Nos. 487 (Singer), 484 (Rysman).3 As is the Court’s practice for Rule 702 motions involving complex expert evidence, the 18 19 Court convened on August 1, 2023, a hot tub focused on the parties’ main disagreements about the 20 admissibility of the merits opinions of Drs. Singer and Rysman. See Dkt. No. 585 (Merits Hot 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 1 Unless otherwise noted, all docket number references are to the ECF docket for the MDL, Case No. 21-md-02981-JD. The Match Group plaintiffs have also filed a motion for partial summary judgment on Google’s counterclaims. Dkt. No. 486. 2 3 The record is a bit fuzzy on whether the plaintiff States in State of Utah v. Google LLC, Case No. 21-cv-05227-JD, intend to rely on Dr. Singer’s opinions at trial. Dr. Singer offers all of his opinions on behalf of the consumer plaintiffs, and a subset on behalf of “the Consumer Plaintiffs and Plaintiff States.” Dkt. No. 489-2 (Singer Merits Report) ¶ 1. Even so, the Court understands that the States are relying primarily on the proposed testimony of Dr. Rysman, which is independent of Dr. Singer’s work. In any event, this order applies to all cases involving Dr. Singer. 2 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 3 of 19 1 Tub Tr.). This time, Google presented Dr. Gregory K. Leonard as its expert economist and not 2 Dr. Burtis, on whom Google had relied for the class certification proceedings. Dr. Leonard is an 3 economist at the consulting firm, Charles River Associates. After the hot tub, the Court posed 4 several questions to Dr. Singer and Dr. Leonard, Dkt. No. 570, which they answered under oath on 5 August 14, 2023. Dkt. Nos. 578, 580. After consideration of the now fully developed record, the merits opinions of Dr. Singer 6 7 are excluded under FRE 702 and the familiar standards in Daubert v. Merrell Dow 8 Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 509 U.S. 579 (1993). The motion to exclude Dr. Rysman’s merits opinions 9 will be addressed in a separate order. 10 BACKGROUND The Court provided an in-depth background for the litigation in the class certification and United States District Court Northern District of California 11 12 expert admissibility order, see Dkt. No. 383 (Class Cert. Order), and will not replow that ground 13 here. The parties’ familiarity with the background is assumed. 14 I. DR. SINGER’S CLASS CERTIFICATION OPINIONS The consumer plaintiffs initially presented Dr. Singer in the class certification proceedings 15 16 to opine on a proposed method of classwide proof of antitrust impact and damages.4 In an expert 17 report prepared with respect to certification, Dr. Singer identified and analyzed two proposed 18 relevant markets for the consumers’ claims: an Android App Distribution Market and an In-App 19 Aftermarket. See Class Cert. Order at 8. For the Android App Distribution Market, Dr. Singer 20 opined that Google’s “take rate,” meaning the share of revenue Google takes from developers for 21 each app sale, would have fallen from 30.1 percent in actual practice to 23.4 percent in a 22 competitive but-for world. This led Dr. Singer to conclude that Play Store users had paid an 23 average overcharge of $0.30 for each app they purchased, resulting in “aggregate damages of 24 $18.76 million” for the proposed class. Id. at 18. For the In-App Aftermarket, which involves 25 26 27 28 4 In his class certification report, Dkt. No. 254-4 (Singer Class Cert. Report), Dr. Singer offered opinions on other elements of the consumer plaintiffs’ antitrust claims, e.g., that Google has engaged in anticompetitive conduct in the Android App Distribution Market and In-App Aftermarket. Google did not challenge the admissibility of those opinions. See Dkt. No. 252. 3 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 4 of 19 1 purchases a user makes within an app after buying it, Dr. Singer opined that Google’s take rate for 2 in-app content would have fallen from 29.2 percent in actual practice to 14.8 percent in a 3 competitive but-for world, resulting in an “average $1.34 consumer savings per transaction and an 4 aggregate damage figure of $4.71 billion.” Id. Dr. Singer offered an alternative damages model 5 based on Google’s Play Points rewards program, and concluded that in a competitive but-for 6 world, the Play Points program would have “expanded to be worth an average of $0.77 per 7 transaction, or approximately 8.7 percent of consumer spend,” resulting in aggregate damages of 8 $2.71 billion. Id. at 22; Singer Class Cert. Report ¶ 255. United States District Court Northern District of California 9 For certification purposes, the Court determined that the Rule 23 questions of commonality 10 and predominance could be answered for the class as a whole on the basis of Dr. Singer’s 11 overcharge models for the Android App Distribution Market and In-App Aftermarket, and so 12 deferred for another day consideration of the Play Points model. Class Cert. Order at 23. The 13 Court overruled Google’s primary objection that Dr. Singer’s overcharge models were 14 inadmissible under FRE 702 because they were based on a faulty “pass-through” formula that 15 Dr. Singer used to quantify how much of Google’s developer fees consumers would ultimately 16 end up paying. As the Court noted, the pass-through formula was a “critical element of 17 Dr. Singer’s overcharge analysis,” and “was an input for both the Rochet-Tirole model (which 18 Dr. Singer used for the Android App Distribution Market) and the Landes-Posner model (used for 19 the In-App Aftermarket).” Id. at 9, 17. The pass-through formula was essential because app 20 developers independently set the prices of the apps and in-app content they make available 21 through the Play Store. The purpose of the pass-through formula was to quantify the “portion of 22 the supracompetitive cost imposed on developers” by Google that was “passed through” to, or 23 more aptly paid by, consumers. Id. at 17. This is a critical part of the consumers’ claim that they 24 overpaid for apps and in-app content as a result of Google’s anticompetitive conduct, and so a 25 classwide method of determining the pass-through rate was vital to the certification motion. 26 Dr. Singer used a pass-through formula “derived from a logit model,” which Dr. Singer 27 believed would correctly model “the demand curve faced by the developers who sell apps and 28 content in the Google Play Store.” Id. Dr. Singer opined in his certification report that “the pass4 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 5 of 19 1 through formula may ultimately be expressed as ‘one minus the share’ an app has in its self- 2 selected Play Store category.” Id. at 17-18. To unpack this at a high level, “category” refers to 3 Google’s own denomination of broad topical groupings such as “education,” “game,” “sports,” 4 and the like used to organize apps in the Play Store. If an app has, say, a 20% share of the sports 5 category, then for that app, Dr. Singer would estimate a pass-through rate of 1 - 20% = 80%. 6 Dr. Singer’s ultimate calculation of the overcharges paid by consumers entails several additional 7 steps, but this logit-based pass-through formula is an essential core element of his overall 8 approach. United States District Court Northern District of California 9 As the proponents of Dr. Singer’s expert testimony, plaintiffs had the burden of 10 establishing its admissibility over Google’s objections. See Southland Sod Farms v. Stover Seed 11 Co., 108 F.3d 1134, 1141-42 (9th Cir. 1997) (plaintiff, as “proponent of scientific evidence” had 12 “burden of establishing that the evidence is scientifically valid,” but nevertheless concluding that 13 “[b]ecause Defendants have not demonstrated that Plaintiffs are unable to make such a showing as 14 a matter of law, we will not exclude [plaintiffs’ expert’s] testimony under Daubert.”). An 15 important aspect of the admissibility analysis at the class certification stage was a careful 16 consideration of the comments made by Google’s proffered expert, Dr. Michelle Burtis, in her 17 certification report and at the hot tub with Dr. Singer. The goal of the hot tub was to provide 18 Google with the opportunity, through its expert, to illuminate its concerns about Dr. Singer’s 19 work, and to give Dr. Singer an opportunity for a real-time response. At the Court’s direction, 20 Dr. Burtis and Dr. Singer jointly prepared a list of discussion topics for the hot tub, in descending 21 order of importance for the question of certification. See Dkt. No. 284, Ex. 1. 22 Critically, for certification purposes, Dr. Burtis did not say that Dr. Singer’s opinions, 23 including his pass-through analysis, were “junk science” that ought to be excluded. See Ellis v. 24 Costco Wholesale Corp., 657 F.3d 970, 982 (9th Cir. 2011). To the contrary, and with specific 25 respect to Dr. Singer’s pass-through model, Dr. Burtis stated: “As I said, the model exists in the 26 literature; and I’m not here to say that this is a model that nobody uses. I won’t say that about this 27 model. Whether it’s the right model, I don’t know, and I don’t have an opinion.” Class Cert. Hot 28 Tub Tr. at 24:12-15. Dr. Burtis also said, again in specific reference to Dr. Singer’s pass-through 5 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 6 of 19 1 model: “Regarding this model, I would say, I don’t think this model itself is junk science. I 2 wouldn’t say that. All I’m saying here is that, you know, Dr. Singer, he didn’t try to adapt the 3 model, to really test the issue of common impact here. He didn’t do anything to test.” Id. at 26:1- 4 5. United States District Court Northern District of California 5 Dr. Burtis’s expert report was equally benign about Dr. Singer’s pass-through formula as a 6 method of analysis. See Dkt. No. 254-5 (Burtis Report). Dr. Burtis devoted three short 7 paragraphs in a 125-page report to the question of whether a logit demand model could, as a 8 matter of sound economics, generate reliable pass-through rates in the Play Store market. Id. at 9 ¶¶ 306-08. She did not say that a credible economist would never use a logit model in the Play 10 Store context. Dr. Burtis agreed that the logit model was “frequently used in economics.” Id. ¶ 11 306. Her main substantive criticism was that Dr. Singer was wrong to use Google’s app 12 categories for the logit analysis, and that he should have come up with his own customized 13 groupings of apps into “more appropriate categories” that would “ensure that substitutes are 14 properly grouped together.” Id. ¶ 311; see also id. ¶ 279 (“The ‘categories’ used by Dr. Singer, 15 which are integral to the results, are not based on any economic analysis or reasoning but are 16 simply the categories used in Google Play.”). Dr. Burtis also faulted Dr. Singer for not accounting 17 for variables such as developers’ marginal costs and pricing strategies to set prices that end in 18 $0.99 cents. See id. ¶¶ 303-04, 313. 19 Overall, Dr. Burtis did not challenge the fundamental soundness of Dr. Singer’s approach 20 in light of the economic literature, and instead offered criticisms that went to the weight of his 21 opinions, and not to admissibility. Consequently, after conducting an independent analysis of 22 Dr. Singer’s work and weighing Google’s objections, the Court determined that Dr. Singer’s 23 testimony was admissible for certification purposes. See Class Cert. Order. Google did not 24 challenge the expert qualifications of Dr. Singer, a well-credentialed economist who is active in 25 the antitrust field. See id. at 8. On the record as it then stood, plaintiffs met their burden of 26 establishing admissibility, and Google and Dr. Burtis did not state objections that demonstrated 27 that Dr. Singer’s opinions warranted exclusion as junk science under Rule 702 or Daubert, 509 28 U.S. 579. 6 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 7 of 19 1 United States District Court Northern District of California 2 II. DR. SINGER’S MERITS OPINIONS The situation has developed at the merits stage. The consumer plaintiffs proffer Dr. Singer 3 again to provide expert testimony on the substance of their antitrust claims, over Google’s 4 objections. Google does not challenge Dr. Singer’s qualifications as an expert, the relevance of 5 his testimony, or all of his opinions. Its motion to exclude is directed only at the injury and 6 damages portions of Dr. Singer’s work, and it challenges his opinions on these topics as unreliable 7 under FRE 702 and Daubert. See Dkt. No. 487. 8 In substantial measure, Dr. Singer’s injury and damages opinions are the same in his class 9 certification and merits reports. The pass-through formula is the same, and Dr. Singer again uses 10 the Rochet-Tirole model for the Android App Distribution Market and the Landes-Posner model 11 for the In-App Aftermarket. Singer Merits Report ¶¶ 288, 326, 358. But this time, Dr. Singer 12 offers aggregate damages figures calculated six different ways: (1) aggregate overcharge damages 13 of $23.83 million for the Android App Distribution Market; (2) aggregate overcharge damages of 14 $7.00 billion for the In-App Aftermarket; (3) a “discount model” based on Google Play Points, 15 calculated for a combined Android App Distribution Market and In-App Aftermarket “where the 16 locus of competition is on the consumer subsidy,” producing $3.92 billion in damages; (4) a 17 “single take rate” damages calculation, “where competition occurs only with respect to the take 18 rate in a single, combined market,” resulting in $3.66 billion in damages; (5) an “Amazon 19 Discount Model,” using the “Amazon Appstore’s consumer discounts” as a “reasonable 20 benchmark for calculating aggregate damages,” producing $8.039 billion in damages; and (6) a 21 single-market “hybrid model,” in which competition occurs with respect to both the take rate and 22 buyer-side subsidy, producing $3.81 billion in aggregate damages. Id. ¶¶ 414-21, 441-45. 23 With respect to the pass-through formula, Dr. Singer again states that, “when demand is 24 logit, a developer’s pass-through rate can be estimated as one minus that developer’s category 25 share.” Id. ¶ 358. The pass-through formula continues to be an essential input in his calculation 26 of aggregate overcharge damages for the Android App Distribution Market, see id. at 141, Table 27 6, and the In-App Aftermarket, see id. at 155, Table 8. The pass-through rate is also an input for 28 the “single take rate” model, see id. at 265, Table A4, and the “hybrid” model, see id. at 267, 7 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 8 of 19 1 Table A5. It is not an input for the “discount” model, see id. at 191, Table 16, or the Amazon 2 Discount model, see id. at 206, Table 21. Google’s response to Dr. Singer has changed since class certification. Most notably, United States District Court Northern District of California 3 4 Dr. Burtis has yielded the floor to a new expert witness, Dr. Leonard. See Dkt. No. 487. 5 Dr. Leonard took a fresh look at Dr. Singer’s opinions and proffered, as will be discussed, a 6 different response from Dr. Burtis. As the Court stated at the merits hot tub, it has some 7 misgivings about Google taking a second shot at Dr. Singer’s testimony with a new witness. Even 8 so, the path to a fair result often has some turns, particularly as the record develops in a complex 9 antitrust dispute such as this one. Consideration of Google’s revised FRE 702 presentation based 10 on a new expert witness serves “the end of ascertaining the truth and securing a just 11 determination” in this multidistrict litigation. Fed. R. Evid. 102. 12 13 DISCUSSION I. LEGAL STANDARDS 14 As Federal Rule of Evidence 702 states, a “witness who is qualified as an expert by 15 knowledge, skill, experience, training, or education may testify in the form of an opinion or 16 otherwise if: (a) the expert’s scientific, technical, or other specialized knowledge will help the 17 trier of fact to understand the evidence or to determine a fact in issue; (b) the testimony is based on 18 sufficient facts or data; (c) the testimony is the product of reliable principles and methods; and 19 (d) the expert has reliably applied the principles and methods to the facts of the case.” 20 This rule is expected to be updated soon. By order of the United States Supreme Court 21 dated April 24, 2023, a proposed amendment to FRE 702 will take effect on December 1, 2023, 22 barring any contrary Congressional action. See https://www.supremecourt.gov/orders/ 23 ordersofthecourt/22 (“4/24/23 Rules of Evidence”); 28 U.S.C. § 2074. The proposed amendment 24 clarifies that an expert witness’s opinion testimony is admissible under FRE 702 only “if the 25 proponent demonstrates to the court that it is more likely than not that” the proposed testimony 26 satisfies subsections (a) through (d) of the Rule. Subsection (d) will also be replaced in its entirety 27 to provide that the expert’s opinion must “reflect[] a reliable application of the principles and 28 methods to the facts of the case.” See Supreme Court’s 4/24/23 Order. In the Court’s view, the 8 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 9 of 19 1 proposed amendment is not a sea change but rather an amplification of existing FRE 702 2 standards. For present purposes, the Court is mindful of FRE 702 as it stands today and as it will 3 be imminently amended. As the Court has observed in another case, the FRE 702 admissibility standard does not 4 5 change with the different stages of litigation or become more rigorous as a case progresses from 6 class certification to the merits stage. See In re Capacitors Antitrust Litigation, MDL Case 7 No. 17-md-02801-JD, 2020 WL 870927, at *2 (N.D. Cal. Feb. 21, 2020). At all stages, “Rule 702 8 of the Federal Rules of Evidence tasks a district court judge with ‘ensuring that an expert’s 9 testimony both rests on a reliable foundation and is relevant to the task at hand.’” Elosu v. 10 Middlefork Ranch Inc., 26 F.4th 1017, 1023 (9th Cir. 2022) (quoting Daubert, 509 U.S. at 597). Reliability is the touchstone. “The test of reliability is flexible,” and “the trial court has United States District Court Northern District of California 11 12 discretion to decide how to test an expert’s reliability as well as whether the testimony is reliable, 13 based on the particular circumstances of the particular case.” Primiano v. Cook, 598 F.3d 558, 14 564 (9th Cir. 2010) (cleaned up). As the amendment of FRE 702 emphasizes, the burden of 15 establishing the reliability of the proposed expert witness testimony rests with the proponent of the 16 expert evidence. See Southland Sod, 108 F.3d at 1141. The Court “must decide any preliminary 17 question about whether a witness is qualified, . . . , or evidence is admissible,” and “[i]n so 18 deciding, the court is not bound by evidence rules, except those on privilege.” Fed. R. Evid. 19 104(a). When “admissibility determinations . . . hinge on preliminary factual questions,” those 20 factual matters must be “established by a preponderance of proof”; application of the 21 “preponderance standard ensures that before admitting evidence, the court will have found it more 22 likely than not that the technical issues and policy concerns addressed by the Federal Rules of 23 Evidence have been afforded due consideration.” Bourjaily v. United States, 483 U.S. 171, 175 24 (1987). 25 II. 26 THE PASS-THROUGH FORMULA In his merits opinions, Dr. Singer used a pass-through formula “specific to logit” that was 27 developed by the economists Nathan Miller, Marc Remer, and Gloria Sheu, and he applied that 28 formula here “to calculate pass-through rates for each Play Store category.” Singer Merits Report 9 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 10 of 19 1 ¶¶ 358, 360. The Google Play Store has approximately 33 app categories for “Beauty,” “Dating,” 2 “Events,” “Health and Fitness,” “Productivity,” “Weather,” and similar categories, and app 3 developers self-select a category when positioning their apps in the Play Store. Id. ¶¶ 349-50 & 4 Table 13. In Dr. Singer’s view, “Miller et. al. demonstrate mathematically that, when firms are 5 subjected to an industrywide change in costs, the profit-maximizing change in the price of a 6 particular product i in response to a one dollar change in a firm’s marginal cost is equal to [M – 7 Qi]/M, where M is the size of the category -- inclusive of the outside good -- and Qi is the quantity 8 sold of product i. This means that, when demand is logit, a developer’s pass-through rate can be 9 estimated as one minus that developer’s category share, consistent with what has been shown 10 United States District Court Northern District of California 11 previously in the peer-reviewed economics literature.” Id. ¶ 358. The reliability of this logit-based pass-through rate depends on whether Dr. Singer reliably 12 “estimate[d] logit demand systems for each of the categories used by Google.” Id. ¶ 354. “In a 13 logit demand system, each product within the system has its own (nonlinear) demand curve, given 14 by the following formula: ln(Sj / S0) = δj + αPj.” Id. ¶ 348. Dr. Singer explains, “Sj is the share of 15 product j, and S0 is the share of the outside good -- that is, the proportion of consumers that do not 16 purchase any of the products at issue. The term δj represents factors other than price that shift 17 demand (and thus share). These are modeled as fixed effects unique to a given App and purchase 18 type (Initial Downloads, In-App, and Subscription). The model also includes fixed effects by 19 state, and for sub-products within a given App (e.g., Pandora Plus versus Pandora Premium).” Id. 20 Dr. Singer states that “[e]conomists have frequently used logit to analyze a variety of economic 21 phenomena, including (but not limited to) potentially anticompetitive conduct in markets with 22 differentiated products.” Id. He also states that “[t]he standard logit model is widely used by 23 economists to estimate pass-through in a range of contexts,” and he acknowledges that the logit 24 demand system implies “that developers in a given category pass through cost savings according 25 to their dominance (or lack thereof) in the category, as measured by their market share within that 26 category.” Id. ¶¶ 351, 356. 27 28 In response to these and related propositions by Dr. Singer, Dr. Leonard presented several new critiques and points of information. The most salient of these concerned the logit model’s 10 United States District Court Northern District of California Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 11 of 19 1 “IIA” property. As Dr. Leonard stated in his report, the logit model “exhibits what is called the 2 ‘independence of irrelevant alternatives’ (IIA) property. The IIA property places strong 3 restrictions on substitution patterns between products (i.e., the own- and cross-price elasticities of 4 demand). Because of IIA’s restrictiveness regarding substitution patterns, from the early 1980s, 5 the economics literature has warned about the use of the logit model of demand.” Dkt. No. 489-3 6 (Leonard Report) at 60 n.76; see also id. ¶ 153. This was new information in that Dr. Burtis had 7 not specifically identified or highlighted the IIA property in a meaningful way. She did not use 8 that term in her report. See Dkt. No. 254-5. She and Dr. Singer did not identify the IIA restriction 9 as a topic for debate at the certification hot tub. See Dkt. No. 284, Ex. 1. During the hot tub 10 discussion, Dr. Burtis never expressly mentioned IIA and made only a passing mention of 11 substitution late in the proceeding. See Dkt. No. 302 at 88:22-91:7. 12 In significant contrast, Dr. Leonard put the IIA property of logit front and center in his 13 challenge to Dr. Singer’s analysis. Dr. Singer does not seriously dispute Dr. Leonard’s 14 observations about the IIA property itself. In the experts’ joint statement of topics for the merits 15 hot tub, Dr. Singer said that he “will address Google’s claim that he misapplied logit because the 16 property of ‘IIA’ or ‘proportional substitution’ -- when prices for one product increase, consumers 17 switch to substitutes in proportion to their relative shares -- is allegedly not satisfied.” Dkt. 18 No. 540-2 at 12. Dr. Singer added that he “will explain that it is reasonable to conclude that the 19 proportional substitution property is satisfied here, as evidenced by his regressions . . . . 20 Moreover, logit is routinely and reliably used as an approximation even when IIA is not strictly 21 satisfied . . . .” Id. Dr. Leonard, on his part, stated that “[o]ne feature of the logit model 22 Dr. Singer used is the ‘irrelevance of independent alternatives’ property, or IIA, which holds that 23 all goods in the market where demand is being studied are substitutes for one another in 24 proportion to their share of that market. There is an economic consensus that if real world 25 demands do not satisfy this property, then the model will yield unreliable results. . . . As applied 26 to demand for Android apps, the IIA principle means that all apps in a given app category must be 27 substitutes for each other, and must be substitutes in proportion to their share of that category. 28 11 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 12 of 19 1 However, Dr. Singer concedes that apps in each category fail this condition. This makes his entire 2 model unreliable.” Id. at 12-13. United States District Court Northern District of California 3 The IIA issue was raised in the parties’ Rule 702 motion briefing, see Dkt. No. 487 at 6-10, 4 Dkt. No. 508 at 5-9, and was discussed in detail at the merits hot tub. In his opening comments 5 about Dr. Singer’s work, Dr. Leonard underscored that “the big problem with the logit model is 6 the so-called IIA assumption. . . . [S]ince probably 1977 or so there have been well-known tests 7 that test for the IIA assumption. And it’s also very well known you shouldn’t just assume logit 8 because it has these very restrictive assumptions on substitution patterns . . . basically a 9 proportional substitution.” Merits Hot Tub Tr. at 27:18-25. Dr. Singer did not take serious issue 10 with Dr. Leonard. When the Court asked, “what is the source of the proportionate substitution or 11 demand proposition, is that Miller?” Dr. Singer said, “Oh, I think it will be in Miller, but it will be 12 on any -- in any -- I don’t think that’s disputed. It’s proportional substitution. That’s what the -- 13 that’s what the IIA property is about.” Id. at 52:8-14. 14 This discussion at the hot tub, and in the merits reports generally, put a much finer point 15 than at class certification on the question of whether Dr. Singer’s logit-based pass-through formula 16 was sufficiently valid and reliable to be admissible. The Court inquired further into the question 17 when it called for additional comments by the economists after the hot tub proceeding. Dkt. 18 No. 570. Among other inquiries, the Court asked: “(A) What economic literature states that a 19 regression analysis is a reliable way of (i) testing for the IIA assumption in the logit model, or 20 (ii) confirming that a logit model can be used to reliably measure the relevant demand curve 21 here?” And, “(B) To what extent can IIA be ‘not strictly satisfied’ before the use of logit model 22 becomes unreliable? How can the Court know that this limit has not been crossed here? How 23 close is the ‘approximation’ that Dr. Singer posits, and how can the Court have confidence that his 24 logit model has produced a sufficiently reliable approximation of pass-through here even if the 25 apps in each category are not proportional substitutes for one another?” Id. at 2. 26 Dr. Singer and Dr. Leonard filed sworn answers to the follow-up questions. Dkt. Nos. 578, 27 580. Dr. Leonard stated that the “defining characteristic of the logit model is the IIA assumption, 28 which forces a particular substitution pattern on the data, regardless of how consumers actually 12 United States District Court Northern District of California Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 13 of 19 1 substitute among products in the marketplace being studied.” Dkt. No. 578 ¶ 6. Dr. Leonard also 2 stated that, in the “specific case of Android apps, given the category definitions that Dr. Singer 3 used, the IIA assumptions of the logit model that all apps are substitutes and substitution is 4 proportional to shares are clearly false,” because “[s]ome of the apps within a category are not 5 substitutes for each other at all, let alone in a manner proportional to their respective shares.” Id. 6 ¶ 19. To illustrate, Dr. Leonard gave the example of “Rosetta Stone,” “Duolingo,” and 7 “PictureThis - Plant Identifier,” which are “three apps in the Education category.” Id. Rosetta 8 Stone has less than a 5% category share; Duolingo has around 15%; and PictureThis - Plant 9 Identifier has around 20%. Id. Dr. Leonard observed that, “[w]ith entirely different functionality 10 than the language learning apps, there can be no serious argument that PictureThis - Plant 11 Identifier is any kind of substitute at all for Rosetta Stone,” and yet, “the logit model, with its IIA 12 assumption, assumes that if Rosetta Stone raised its price and some customers substituted away, 13 PictureThis - Plant Identifier would capture a larger percentage of these switching customers than 14 Duolingo . . . simply because PictureThis - Plant Identifier has a larger category share than 15 Duolingo.” Id. In Dr. Leonard’s view, “[t]his makes no economic sense at all.” Id. 16 Dr. Singer stated in his response to the follow-up questions that “IIA is a property of 17 logit,” and “[a]pplied here, IIA implies that consumers will tend to substitute among different 18 Apps within a given category in proportion to an Apps’ share in that category (‘proportional 19 substitution’ or ‘proportionate shifting’).” Dkt. No. 580 ¶ 13. Dr. Singer’s comments were 20 consistent with Dr. Leonard in terms of how the IIA assumption would be expected to play out in 21 the context of apps in the Play Store: “Suppose the price of App A increases. To avoid the price 22 hike, some consumers will switch to different Apps within the same category. Suppose further 23 that App B is very popular, with a category share of 50 percent, and that App C is less popular, 24 with a category share of just one percent. Under proportional substitution, these consumers are 25 more likely to switch to the (more popular) App B than they are to switch to the (less popular) App 26 C. Specifically, consumers are, on average, fifty times more likely to switch to App B than App C 27 under this assumption.” Id. 28 13 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 14 of 19 United States District Court Northern District of California 1 Critically, Dr. Singer did not explain why this assumption would still make economic 2 sense if App A and App C were more similar, like Duolingo and Rosetta Stone, and App B were 3 entirely different, such as PictureThis - Plant Identifier. As Dr. Leonard suggests, it is intuitively 4 obvious that users looking for an app to learn Italian will not try to avoid a price hike by switching 5 to an app that identifies the type of geranium in their kitchen. This intuition highlights a 6 fundamental problem that a jury would face if Dr. Singer’s opinions were presented at trial. It 7 may be possible for a jury to make reasonable decisions about the substitutability of certain apps 8 at a very high and general level, but Dr. Singer’s analysis does not provide usable guidance on 9 what to do with the myriad of differences and distinctions between apps within the Google Play 10 Store categories. He does not provide any boundaries on substitution in broad app categories that 11 contain many unlike products. This would create a serious risk of the jury simply guessing about 12 proportionate substitution and ultimately the pass-through of fees to consumers. 13 Dr. Singer’s position with respect to the IIA property of logit is further eroded by one of 14 the main authorities he cited in his follow-up response and attached in full as an exhibit: Kenneth 15 Train, Logit, in Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation 34 (Cambridge University Press 2009). 16 See Dkt. No. 580, Ex. 15. Professor Train’s chapter on logit deepens rather than alleviates the 17 Court’s concern that the logit model cannot be reliably used in the context of apps in the Google 18 Play Store in the way Dr. Singer has done in his analysis. Professor Train starts with the 19 observation that “[b]y far the easiest and most widely used discrete choice model is logit.” Id. at 20 34. He explains that “[i]ts popularity is due to the fact that the formula for the choice probabilities 21 takes a closed form and is readily interpretable.” Id. 22 From there, he sounds many cautionary notes about the appropriateness of its use. He 23 states, for example, that “[l]ogit models can capture taste variations, but only within limits. In 24 particular, tastes that vary systematically with respect to observed variables can be incorporated in 25 logit models, while tastes that vary with unobserved variables or purely randomly cannot be 26 handled.” Id. at 43. Also, “if taste variation is at least partly random, logit is a misspecification. 27 As an approximation, logit might be able capture the average tastes fairly well even when tastes 28 are random, since the logit formula seems to be fairly robust to misspecifications. The researcher 14 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 15 of 19 1 might therefore choose to use logit even when she knows that tastes have a random component, 2 for the sake of simplicity. However, there is no guarantee that a logit model will approximate the 3 average tastes. And even if it does, logit does not provide information on the distribution of tastes 4 around the average. This distribution can be important in many situations . . . .” Id. at 44. 5 Further, “[p]roportionate substitution can be realistic for some situations, in which case the logit 6 model is appropriate. In many settings, however, other patterns of substitution can be expected, 7 and imposing proportionate substitution through the logit model can lead to unrealistic forecasts.” 8 Id. at 48. These comments support Dr. Leonard’s critiques and undercut the reliability of United States District Court Northern District of California 9 10 Dr. Singer’s work. Dr. Singer endeavors to use the logit model in an overly simple way to 11 represent the demand curve for developers in the Play Store. In Dr. Singer’s model, when the 12 price of an app goes up, the consumer will necessarily switch to a different app in the same 13 category, based purely on the popularity of those other apps. As Dr. Singer acknowledges, this 14 approach works only if the apps within each category are proportional substitutes for one another. 15 This is an unproven assumption in Dr. Singer’s work. It cannot be squared with the economic 16 literature such as that of Professor Train, and it flies in the face of the huge diversity of apps 17 within the Play Store categories. As Dr. Leonard has noted, given the broad categories in the 18 Google Play Store, which developers self-select, the IIA’s assumption that “all apps are substitutes 19 and substitution is proportional to shares” is not factually supported in this context. Dkt. No. 578 20 ¶ 19. 21 Dr. Singer’s main defense is to say that “IIA is reliably established here” because he has 22 “confirmed using standard regression methods from the economic literature that the logit demand 23 curve is well-specified here.” Dkt. No. 580 at 8. The problem is that nothing validates the use of 24 regressions in this manner. Professor Train certainly did not identify this kind of regression 25 analysis as a way of validating a use of logit. He did say that the “independence assumption . . . in 26 fact can be interpreted as a natural outcome of a well-specified model,” and that “[i]n a deep 27 sense, the ultimate goal of the researcher is to represent utility so well that the only remaining 28 aspects constitute simply white noise; that is, the goal is to specify utility well enough that a logit 15 United States District Court Northern District of California Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 16 of 19 1 model is appropriate. Seen in this way, the logit model is the ideal rather than a restriction.” Id., 2 Ex. 15 at 35-36. But this observation does not appear to fit Dr. Singer’s model. He has not 3 specified his observed variables so well that “the remaining, unobserved portion of utility is 4 essentially ‘white noise.’” Id. at 35. Rather, as Dr. Leonard notes, Dr. Singer’s model “includes 5 only the app price and a set of SKU-time-state indicator variables. This leaves plenty of room for 6 substantial correlation among the remaining unobserved portions of a consumer’s utilities for 7 apps. For example, consumers who like a given single-shooter game likely also like other single- 8 shooter games . . . . That is, such consumers will exhibit positive correlation among unobserved 9 parts of their utilities for single-shooter games. The unobserved portions of their utilities are not 10 just ‘white noise.’ The price and indicator variables included in Dr. Singer’s model would not 11 capture this correlation in consumers’ preferences over single-shooter games and therefore the 12 ‘ideal’ would not be met and the logit model would not apply.” Dkt. No. 578 ¶ 29. 13 Dr. Leonard has also pointed out that Dr. Singer did not compare the “fit” of the logit 14 model with “that of an alternative demand model.” Id. ¶ 14. And in Dr. Leonard’s view, 15 Dr. Singer’s claim that he “obtained the ‘right’ signs and statistical significance on the price 16 coefficients in his regression model as support for the logit model” is “a low bar,” because “all 17 demand models predict lower share (i.e., lower quantity) when price increases and vice versa.” Id. 18 at 8 n.9. Similarly, the States’ expert, Dr. Rysman, was asked in his deposition whether it would 19 be sufficient for him “to determine that a standard logit model was appropriate that there was a 20 negative correlation between price and demand,” and he responded, “Not by itself[,] that wouldn’t 21 tell me that the logit model was appropriate.” Dkt. No. 487-4 at 68:21-69:2. While plaintiffs have 22 pointed out that Dr. Rysman “had not read Dr. Singer’s report,” Dkt. No. 508 at 7 n.5, it is hard to 23 see why that would matter for purposes of the answer Dr. Rysman gave, which stands on its own 24 and bolsters Dr. Leonard’s critique of Dr. Singer’s work. 25 Overall, the record at the merits stage is substantially more developed than at class 26 certification, and establishes that Dr. Singer’s pass-through model is not within accepted economic 27 theory and literature, and is based on assumptions about the Play Store apps that are not supported 28 by the evidence. The model does not give the jury a sound basis on which to make a reasoned and 16 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 17 of 19 1 reasonable judgment about antitrust impact and damages in a product market that does not show 2 proportional substitution across alternatives, at least not on a Play Store category share basis as 3 Dr. Singer has modeled. Because that pass-through model is the keystone of Dr. Singer’s overcharge analysis, his United States District Court Northern District of California 4 5 opinions based on it must be excluded. The purpose of judicial gatekeeping under Rule 702 is “to 6 make certain that an expert . . . employs in the courtroom the same level of intellectual rigor that 7 characterizes the practice of an expert in the relevant field.” Kumho Tire Co., Ltd. v. Carmichael, 8 526 U.S. 137, 152 (1999). Dr. Singer’s use of a logit approach to model the demand curve faced 9 by app developers in the Play Store, ultimately producing the simple pass-through formula of one 10 minus the app’s share of its category, was a decision that “fell outside the range where experts 11 might reasonably differ, and where the jury must decide among the conflicting views of different 12 experts, even though the evidence is ‘shaky.’” Id. at 153 (quoting Daubert, 509 U.S. at 596). 13 Because the characteristics of a logit model and its IIA property are enough to find that 14 Dr. Singer’s pass-through formula here is not sufficiently reliable to be admitted under Rule 702, 15 the Court declines to reach Google’s other arguments that the pass-through formula suffers from 16 additional admissibility shortcomings.5 Since Dr. Singer’s pass-through formula is not reliable 17 enough to be admitted, his testimony about that formula, and his injury and damages opinions that 18 necessarily rely on it, are excluded. 19 III. As an alternative approach, Dr. Singer offered “consumer subsidy” models that did not use 20 21 THE CONSUMER SUBSIDY MODELS the pass-through formula. Opinions with respect to these models are also excluded. The main reason for exclusion is that the analysis behind the subsidy models is too anemic 22 23 to let them go to a jury. For the Play Points model, Dr. Singer relies on wholly speculative 24 assumptions that make his opinions ipse dixit unsuitable for admission at trial. For example, he 25 states, with no visible factual support, that “the structure of Play Points is a reasonable facsimile of 26 27 28 Google’s motion for leave to file a supplemental brief in support of its Rule 702 motion, Dkt. No. 541, is granted. For the sake of deciding this issue on as complete a record as possible, the Court reviewed and considered Google’s supplemental brief and attachments, as well as plaintiffs’ opposition and attached supplemental reports. Dkt. Nos. 541-1, 550. 17 5 United States District Court Northern District of California Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 18 of 19 1 what an expanded program might look like in a competitive but-for world,” Singer Merits Report 2 ¶ 373, and that “[c]onsumers would have enhanced economic incentives to enroll and participate 3 in a Play Points offering more valuable incentives in the but-for world, just as consumers have 4 more incentives to participate in a more generous credit card rewards program than a less generous 5 one.” Id. ¶ 381. Why any of this might be true is not said. Dr. Singer’s Play Points calculations 6 also rest on the assumption that, in the but-for world, Google “maintains a 60 percent market share 7 with an inelastic supply response from Google’s rivals.” Id. ¶ 386. Dr. Singer says that “[e]ven in 8 the presence of substantial competition, I assume conservatively that Google would have retained 9 a substantial market share of 60 percent,” because “this was approximately AT&T’s market share 10 in the long-distance market after competitive entry.” Id. ¶ 331. It is again not explained, and is 11 certainly not obvious, why the situation AT&T faced in the telecom market in the 1980s is a good 12 benchmark for Google’s app store practices today. As Dr. Leonard aptly commented, “[t]he 13 economics of long distance service in the 1980s and early 1990s differed substantially from the 14 but-for world for Android app stores in this case,” and “without an in-depth analysis,” there is an 15 insufficient basis “to think that the entry costs, requirements, and market opportunity for one or 16 more new firms to compete with the incumbent would be the same in the Android app store 17 marketplace as was the case in the 1980s and early 1990s long distance service marketplace.” 18 Dkt. No. 578 ¶¶ 43-44. 19 So too for Dr. Singer’s other consumer subsidy model. Dr. Singer devotes a paltry four 20 paragraphs to a purported Amazon Coins discount damages model. Singer Merits Report ¶¶ 417- 21 20. Not surprisingly, those four paragraphs do not adequately explain why or how the Amazon 22 Appstore might be a “reasonable approximation” of damages here. Id. ¶ 418. Dr. Singer again 23 simply asserts, with no real analysis or data, that “Amazon’s aggregate discount . . . on third-party 24 devices is a reasonable benchmark for estimating aggregate damages.” Id. ¶ 419. 25 “[N]othing in either Daubert or the Federal Rules of Evidence requires a district court to 26 admit opinion evidence that is connected to existing data only by the ipse dixit of the expert. A 27 court may conclude that there is simply too great an analytical gap between the data and the 28 18 Case 3:20-cv-05761-JD Document 448 Filed 08/28/23 Page 19 of 19 1 opinion proffered.” General Electric Co. v. Joiner, 522 U.S. 136, 146 (1997). That is the case 2 here for Dr. Singer’s consumer subsidy models. 3 4 5 6 7 CONCLUSION Google’s motion to exclude the merits opinion testimony of Dr. Singer, Dkt. No. 487, is granted. IT IS SO ORDERED. Dated: August 28, 2023 8 9 JAMES DONATO United States District Judge 10 United States District Court Northern District of California 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 19

Some case metadata and case summaries were written with the help of AI, which can produce inaccuracies. You should read the full case before relying on it for legal research purposes.

This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.