Electric Power Supply Associat v. Anthony Star, No. 17-2445 (7th Cir. 2018)

Annotate this Case
Download PDF
In the United States Court of Appeals For the Seventh Circuit ____________________ Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 ELECTRIC POWER SUPPLY ASSOCIATION, et al., Plaintiffs Appellants, v. ANTHONY M. STAR, Director of the Illinois Power Agency, et al., Defendants Appellees. ____________________ Appeals from the United States District Court for the Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division. Nos. 17 CV 1163 and 17 CV 1164 — Manish S. Shah, Judge. ____________________ ARGUED JANUARY 3, 2018 — DECIDED SEPTEMBER 13, 2018 ____________________ Before EASTERBROOK and SYKES, Circuit Judges, and REAGAN, District Judge* EASTERBROOK, Circuit Judge. Regional transmission organ izations manage the interstate grid for electricity. See, e.g., Benton County Wind Farm LLC v. Duke Energy Indiana, Inc., * Of the Southern District of Illinois, sitting by designation. 2 Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 843 F.3d 298 (7th Cir. 2016); MISO Transmission Owners v. FERC, 819 F.3d 329 (7th Cir. 2016). Midcontinent Independ ent System Operator (MISO) and PJM Interconnection han dle the grid in and around the Midwest. Many large genera tors of electricity sell most if not all of their power through auctions conducted by regional organizations, which are regulated by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission. States must not interfere with these auctions. Hughes v. Talen Energy Marketing, LLC, 136 S. Ct. 1288 (2016). Illinois has enacted legislation subsidizing some of the state’s nuclear generation facilities, which the state fears will close. 20 ILCS 3855/1 75(d 5). These favored producers re ceive what the state calls “zero emission credits” or ZECs. (We call them credits.) Generators that use coal or gas to produce power must purchase these credits from the recipi ents at a price set by the state. The price of each credit is $16.50 per megawatt hour, a number Illinois derived from a federal working group’s calculation of the social cost of car bon emissions. (Coal and gas plants emit carbon dioxide; nuclear, wind, solar, and hydro plants don’t.) The price per credit falls if a “market price index” exceeds $31.40 per meg awatt hour. Illinois derives this index from the annual aver age energy prices in the auction conducted by PJM and the prices in two of the state’s regional energy markets. The ad justment is designed “to ensure that the procurement [of electricity] remains a ordable to retail customers … if elec tricity prices increase”. 20 ILCS 3855/1 75(d 5)(1)(B). Plainti s (an association representing electricity produc ers, plus several municipalities) contend that the price adjustment aspect of the state’s system leads to preemption by the Federal Power Act because it impinges on the FERC’s Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 3 regulatory authority. They concede that a state may take many steps that a ect the price of power. It may levy a tax on carbon emissions. It may tax the assets and incomes of power producers. It may use tax revenues to subsidize some or all generators of power. It may create a cap and trade sys tem under which every firm that emits carbon must buy credits in a market (firms that emit less carbon, or none, will be the sellers). As plainti s see matters, although such sys tems a ect the price in the PJM and MISO auctions, they do not regulate that price. But the zero emission credit system, plainti s insist, indirectly regulates the auction by using av erage auction prices as a component in a formula that a ects the cost of a credit. The district judge did not agree with this argument and granted summary judgment to the defend ants. 2017 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 109368 (N.D. Ill. July 14, 2017). The parties’ briefs address a number of procedural ques tions. These include whether a claim of preemption may be presented directly under the Supremacy Clause of the Con stitution and whether relief under the theory of Ex parte Young, 209 U.S. 123 (1908), would be appropriate against the state defendants in light of remedies potentially available under the Federal Power Act. See Armstrong v. Exceptional Child Center, 135 S. Ct. 1378 (2015); Verizon Maryland, Inc. v. Public Service Commission of Maryland, 535 U.S. 635 (2002). But none of the procedural disputes concerns subject matter jurisdiction, which rests on both 28 U.S.C. §1331 (federal question jurisdiction) and 16 U.S.C. §825p (authorizing suits in equity to enforce the Federal Power Act). Because the dis trict court’s jurisdiction is secure, we can go straight to the merits—for, if we decide that federal law does not preempt the state statute, none of the procedural issues matters. 4 Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 At oral argument we expressed concern that the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission had not decided whether Illinois has interfered with its authority over auctions for in terstate power. After receiving submissions from the liti gants addressing the possibility of invoking the doctrine of primary jurisdiction (another non jurisdictional doctrine, de spite its name) and waiting for the FERC to act on petitions pending before it, we decided to ask the agency to give us its views as an amicus curiae. The Commission and the United States then filed a joint brief concluding that Illinois’ pro gram does not interfere with interstate auctions and is not otherwise preempted. More briefs from the parties followed, and the appeals are at last ready for decision. The Federal Power Act divides regulatory authority be tween states and the FERC. The Commission regulates the sale of electricity in interstate commerce (including auctions conducted by regional organizations), while states regulate local distribution plus the facilities used to generate power. 16 U.S.C. §824(b)(1). This allocation leads to conflict, because what states do in the exercise of their powers a ects inter state sales, just as what the FERC does in the exercise of its powers a ects the need for and economic feasibility of plants over which the states possess authority. For decades the Su preme Court has attempted to confine both the Commission and the states to their proper roles, while acknowledging that each use of authorized power necessarily a ects tasks that have been assigned elsewhere. See, e.g., Federal Power Commission v. Southern California Edison Co., 376 U.S. 205 (1964); FERC v. Electric Power Supply Association, 136 S. Ct. 760 (2016). Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 5 Hughes, the most recent of these decisions, draws a line between state laws whose e ect depends on a utility’s par ticipation in an interstate auction (forbidden) and state laws that do not so depend but that may a ect auctions (allowed). 136 S. Ct. at 1297. The FERC has a policy that o ers some price protection to new producers for the first three years of their participation in an auction. Maryland, concluding that three years is too short to encourage the addition of genera tion capacity, asked the Commission to increase the price protection window to a decade. It declined. Maryland then decided to create price protection on its own by requiring older utilities to sign 20 year contracts with new entrants guaranteeing them a price floor, provided they sold their power in FERC regulated auctions. As long as an entrant bid a price low enough to prevail in an auction, other producers had to make up the di erence between that price and the guarantee. Because it is always possible to sell power in an auction by making a su ciently low bid (PJM allows even negative bids, under which a producer o ers to pay custom ers to take power o its hands), the Maryland system e ec tively allocated to new entrants a long term right of first sale in the auction and in the process depressed the price that other producers would receive. This feature—that the subsi dy depended on selling power in the interstate auction—is what led the Justices to conclude that Maryland had trans gressed a domain reserved to the FERC. The Court stressed that its decision covers only state rules that depend on participating in the interstate auction, stating: “States, of course, may regulate within the domain Congress assigned to them even when their laws incidental ly a ect areas within FERC’s domain.” Hughes, 136 S. Ct. at 1298. “Nothing in this opinion should be read to foreclose 6 Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 [states] from encouraging production of new or clean gener ation through measures ‘untethered to a generator’s whole sale market participation.’” Id. at 1299. And that’s what Illi nois has done. To receive a credit, a firm must generate pow er, but how it sells that power is up to it. It can sell the power in an interstate auction but need not do so. It may choose in stead to sell power through bilateral contracts with users (such as industrial plants) or local distribution companies that transmit the power to residences. If a producer does o er power to an interstate auction, the value of a credit does not depend on its bid. True, the outcome of all PJM auctions, averaged over a year, may a ect the value of a credit (if the average exceeds $31.40), but what (indeed, whether) a producer bids in the interstate auc tion does not determine the amount it receives. Every suc cessful bidder in an interstate auction receives the price of the highest bid that clears the market. Hughes, 136 S. Ct. at 1293. The owner of a credit receives that market clearing price, with none of the adjustments that Maryland law re quired. The zero emissions credit system can influence the auction price only indirectly, by keeping active a generation facility that otherwise might close and by raising the costs that carbon releasing producers incur to do business. A larg er supply of electricity means a lower market clearing price, holding demand constant. But because states retain authori ty over power generation, a state policy that a ects price on ly by increasing the quantity of power available for sale is not preempted by federal law. “So long as a State does not condition payment of funds on capacity clearing the [inter state] auction, the State’s program [does] not su er from the fatal defect that renders Maryland’s program unacceptable.” Id. at 1299. Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 7 This does not imply that PJM, MISO, and the Commis sion are unconcerned about the e ect of state programs de signed to subsidize producers of electricity. PJM has asked the Commission to approve changes to its auction design in order to improve the system’s price discovery and output allocation e ects in the wake of laws such as the one Illinois enacted. Recently the FERC declined to approve PJM’s pro posal and opened a new proceeding so that the Commission may determine for itself what changes, if any, should be made to auctions for interstate sales of electricity. Calpine Corp. v. PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 163 FERC ¶61,236 (June 29, 2018). Plainti s insist that the need to revamp the auction system shows that the Illinois statute must be preempted. But that’s not what the Commission said. Instead of deeming state systems such as Illinois’ to be forbidden, the Commission has taken them as givens and set out to make the best of the situation they produce. It wrote: “We empha size that an expanded [Minimum O er Price Rule] in no way divests the states in the PJM region of their jurisdiction over generation facilities. States may continue to support their preferred types of resources in pursuit of state policy goals.” Order at ¶158. As the Supreme Court remarked in Hughes, the exercise of powers reserved to the states under §824(b)(1) a ects interstate sales. Those e ects do not lead to preemp tion; they are instead an inevitable consequence of a system in which power is shared between state and national gov ernments. Once the Commission reaches a final decision in the ongoing proceeding, the adequacy of its adjustments will be subject to judicial review; the need to make adjustments in light of states’ exercise of their lawful powers does not diminish the scope of those powers. 8 Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 A few words about the Constitution and we are done. Plainti s invoke the dormant Commerce Clause and its rule that states may not discriminate against interstate transac tions. See, e.g., United Haulers Association, Inc. v. Oneida Herkimer Solid Waste Management Authority, 550 U.S. 330 (2007). Plainti s observe that the credits are bound to help some Illinois firms and contend that this condemns them. But this amounts to saying that the powers reserved to the states by §824(b)(1) are denied to the states by the Constitu tion, because state regulatory authority is limited to the state’s territory. On this view, whenever Illinois, or any other state, takes some step that will increase or reduce the state’s aggregate generation capacity, or a ect the price of energy, then the state policy is invalid. That can’t be right; it would be the end of federalism. The Commerce Clause does not “cut the States o from legislating on all subjects relating to the health, life, and safety of their citizens, [just because] the legislation might indirectly a ect the commerce of the coun try.” General Motors Corp. v. Tracy, 519 U.S. 278, 306 (1997). The commerce power belongs to Congress; the Supreme Court treats silence by Congress as preventing discriminato ry state legislation. Yet Congress has not been silent about electricity: it provided in §824(b)(1) that states may regulate local generation. In Prudential Insurance Co. v. Benjamin, 328 U.S. 408 (1946), the Court rejected a constitutional challenge to a statute that permits states to close their borders to insur ance written in other states—a statute that even permits states to supersede national legislation on the topic of insur ance. Section 824(b)(1) does not go that far; it does not au thorize express discrimination. But it does mean that the balancing approach of decisions such as Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137 (1970), which ask whether a state’s interest Nos. 17 2433 & 17 2445 9 is strong enough to justify an interstate e ect, does not apply to a state’s regulation of electric capacity or a cross subsidy between carbon emitting generation and carbon free genera tion. Illinois has not engaged in any discrimination beyond what is required by the rule that a state must regulate within its borders. All carbon emitting plants in Illinois need to buy credits. The subsidy’s recipients are in Illinois; so are the payors. The price e ect of the statute is felt wherever the power is used. All power (from inside and outside Illinois) goes for the same price in an interstate auction. The cross subsidy among producers may injure investors in carbon releasing plants, but only those plants in Illinois (for the state’s regulatory power stops at the border). The combina tion of §824(b)(1) and the absence of overt discrimination de feats any constitutional challenge to the state’s legislation. AFFIRMED

Some case metadata and case summaries were written with the help of AI, which can produce inaccuracies. You should read the full case before relying on it for legal research purposes.

This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.